Friday, November 30, 2012
The Mortgage Interest Deduction: Will the Sacred Cow Finally Get Roasted?
Don't count on it. But the very fact that the enormous government subsidy that is the mortgage interest deduction is being discussed in the 'fiscal cliff' chatter is remarkable. The Washington Post reports that the most sacred of sacred cows suddenly looks tasty to lawmakers.
The article even contains a nice quote from a law prof:
Edward Kleinbard, a tax expert and law professor at the University of
Southern California, said the mortgage-interest deduction represents the kind of
government “extravagance” that the country no longer can justify, given its
fiscal troubles.
“We simply cannot afford wasteful government subsidy programs anymore, and
this is one of the most important examples of that,” Kleinbard said. “It’s very
much a subsidy to those Americans who need it least.”
Professor Kleinbard is right: the mortgage interest deduction is a strange and regressive tax subsidy. It benefits most those who need it least. And, it encourages borrowing and discourages homeowners from putting equity in their homes.
And yet, it is so deeply embedded in our real estate system that almost every home in America would have to be devalued if it was eliminated, because potential buyers figure the deduction into the amount they can pay for a home. And it has friends with money and influence: the construction industry, realtors, lenders.
Still, its long term future isn't as rosy as it once seemed. Logically, it ought to be at least capped if not scrapped. But a cap would hurt those best able to make sure there is no cap, so I'm guessing we'll still be having this discussion many, many years from now. What do you think?
Mark A. Edwards
November 30, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
More on the Chinese "Kelo Case"
Ilya Somin has a detailed follow-up on the recent property dispute in China that has drawn some comparisons to Kelo.
Steve ClowneyNovember 30, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Bronin on Incorporating Renewable Energy into Building Projects
Sara Bronin (Connecticut) has posted Building-Related Renewable Energy and the Case of 360 State Street (Vanderbilt Law Review) on SSRN. Here's the abstract:
This
Article argues that a well-conceived policy approach to building-related
renewable energy (“BRRE”) — that is, renewable energy incorporated into
inhabited structures and used by those structures’ occupants — could
transform the way we produce and consume energy by maximizing efficiency
while simultaneously minimizing energy sprawl.
The vast
majority of Americans favor renewable energy, at least in concept. Yet
private property owners still face significant obstacles in trying to
incorporate renewable energy into their projects. This Article analyzes
barriers faced by the project team for 360 State Street, an
award-winning, mixed-use LEED® Platinum building in downtown New Haven,
Connecticut. Among other features, the project incorporates one of the
first fuel cells in a multifamily residential building in the world,
uses 55 percent less electricity than a standard code-compliant
building, must abide by a development agreement with the municipality
requiring certain commitments to sustainability, and has become a poster
child for the LEED® for Neighborhood Development program. It is an
ideal case study because information about it is readily available; the
project team considered multiple types of BRRE and coupled one type of
BRRE with significant energy efficiency measures; and its primary
funding comes from a single private source, meaning that the impact of
renewable energy financing rules on decision-making can be more easily
discerned than it might be in other projects that involve primarily
public, or multiple private, sources.
A case study can help
confirm or rebut assumptions in the legal literature about the impact of
BRRE-related law and policy on private decision-making. As this Article
shows, the case study suggests that while legal scholars have focused
primarily on issues related to the installation of BRRE, issues related
to the operation of BRRE may be just as, if not more, significant to
prospective BRRE developers. BRRE can be expanded if scholars and
policymakers address barriers, particularly at the state level, to fully
utilizing BRRE capacity once it is installed.
Steve Clowney
November 30, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Thursday, November 29, 2012
When Your Art Isn't Art
Slate has a weirdly interesting article on what happens when insurance agents decide that a piece of art is no longer art:
To give a brief explanation of art that is no longer art: Sometimes the cost of restoring a work of art exceeds the value of the work, in which case the insurer declares a total loss, and the work is declared no longer art—that is, of no market value. The damage can range from obvious to subtle—from a ripped painting or shattered sculpture to a wrinkle in a photographic print, or mold damage which can’t be seen at all. As it wouldn't do to send the not-artwork to the crematorium—the work might be of scholarly value, or might one day be worth repairing, or might one day be more easily repaired—the work is stored, not dead, but in a state of indefinite coma. The Salvage Art Institute, Elka's curatorial brainchild, collects and exhibits not-art.
Steve Clowney
November 29, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Land Use in the Nation's Capitol
Over at the Atlantic Cities Blog, David Schleicher (George Mason) takes on D.C.'s height restrictions:
I don’t think the basic look of D.C. would be at risk if the Height Act was repealed. And I think these aesthetic values are odd, at best. But if you do love D.C.’s aesthetic and have a different view of local politics than I do, at what point would the value of keeping the aesthetic become too costly? Ryan Avent estimates that as of 1998, the “shadow tax" of the Height Act and other restrictions in downtown D.C. alone equaled roughly $1.4B in forgone real estate value. (And that was using 1998 numbers, so it’s a very conservative figure.) At what point does imposing a particular aesthetic become too costly? Is there a dollar figure one associates with this kind of thing? If not, why not?
Steve Clowney
November 29, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Wednesday, November 28, 2012
NIMBYism in Cambridge
Matt Yglesias highlights how Cambridge's progressive political orientation dissolves when residents think about local land use issues:
[M]aybe Cambridge residents just don't care about the welfare of their fellow citizen. But if you put it to them squarely, I bet they'd say they do. These are voters who favor, quite sincerely, progressive taxation, and a robust social safety net. They just don't think of these local policy issues in the same terms, as questions that have broad implications for human welfare and aren't just of parochial interest.
Steve Clowney
November 28, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
The Urbanization of the Amazon
The New York Times reports that urban spaces are rapidly encroaching on the heart of the Amazon jungle:
Of the 19 Brazilian cities that the latest census indicates have doubled in population over the past decade, 10 are in the Amazon. Altogether, the region’s population climbed 23 percent from 2000 to 2010, while Brazil as a whole grew just 12 percent.
Various factors are fueling this growth, among them larger family sizes and the Amazon’s high levels of poverty in comparison with other regions that draw people to the cities for work. While Brazil’s birthrate has fallen to 1.86 children per woman, one of the lowest in Latin America, the Amazon has Brazil’s highest rate, at 2.42.
It also appears that Brazilian property law has played a role in the luring migrants to the jungle. The country encourages settlement by granting legal title to squatters who occupy land in the Amazon region.
Steve Clowney
November 28, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Mettler on Graffiti Ordinances
Margaret Mettler (Michigan - Student) has posted Graffiti Museum: A First Amendment Argument for Protecting Uncommissioned Art on Private Property on SSRN. Here's the abstract:
Graffiti
has long been a target of municipal legislation that aims to preserve
property values, public safety, and aesthetic integrity in the
community. Not only are graffitists at risk of criminal prosecution but
property owners are subject to civil and criminal penalties for
harboring graffiti on their land. Since the 1990s, most U.S. cities have
promulgated graffiti abatement ordinances that require private property
owners to remove graffiti from their land, often at their own expense.
These ordinances define graffiti broadly to include essentially any
surface marking applied without advance authorization from the property
owner.
Meanwhile, graffiti has risen in prominence as a
legitimate art form, beginning in the 1960s and most recently with the
contributions of street artists such as Banksy and Shepard Fairey. Some
property owners may find themselves fortuitous recipients of “graffiti”
they deem art and want to preserve in spite of graffiti abatement
ordinances and sign regulations requiring the work’s removal. This Note
argues that private property owners who wish to preserve uncommissioned
art on their land can challenge these laws under the First Amendment,
claiming that, as applied, regulations requiring removal are
unconstitutional because they leave the property owner insufficient
alternative channels for expression.
Steve Clowney
November 28, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Tuesday, November 27, 2012
If You Buy the Twinkie Brand What Do You Get?
Slate contemplates what will become of the Twinkie after the Hostess bankruptcy:
Historic brands like Twinkies, Wonder Bread, and Ho Hos will be sold at auction to the highest bidder. Will the buyers get the exclusive right to use the recipes for those products?
Not exactly. Confectioners rarely patent their recipes, because applying with the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office means publishing the ingredients and methods. The legal protection lasts only 20 years, after which time anyone can profit from the creation. Manufacturers instead guard their recipes as trade secrets, a status that isn’t time-limited. The company forces employees to sign nondisclosure agreements and sues rival manufacturers that extract their methods and formulas from workers. The companies that eventually buy Hostess brands will gain access to those trade secrets and the right to enforce the secrecy agreements. If, however, someone cracks the Twinkie recipe and manufactures an identical product under a different name—the brand names are protected by trademark—there’s very little the new owner will be able to do.
Steve Clowney
November 27, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Rule on Wind Rights
Troy Rule (Missouri) has posted Wind Rights under Property Law: Answers Still Blowing in the Wind (Property & Probate) on SSRN. Here's the abstract:
The
rising economic value of wind resources in recent years has introduced
some perplexing new property law questions. For example, what exactly
are “wind rights”, and are they legally cognizable real property
interests? Should landowners be liable if wind turbines on their
parcels disrupt the energy productivity of wind flowing onto downwind
property? Can landowners legally sever a “wind estate” from their land
and transfer it separately from the surface rights, like a mineral
estate? And should a wind energy restriction that effectively
appropriates private airspace for a specific government entity’s own use
trigger a compensable regulatory taking?
Although a handful of
state legislatures have recently enacted laws seeking to clarify the
nature and scope of wind rights, significant uncertainty surrounding
these rights remains. Such uncertainty can deter investment in wind
farms and impede wind energy development. In an era of shrinking state
budgets and dwindling government subsidies for alternative energy, laws
that provide greater certainty regarding wind rights are a low-cost way
for states to promote wind energy development within their
jurisdictions. This short magazine article examines a handful of
unresolved property law issues involving wind energy and briefly
describes some potential policy strategies for addressing these issues.
Steve Clowney
November 27, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Monday, November 26, 2012
A Chinese Susette Kelo?
China takes a slightly different approach to takings:
A new motorway in China has been built around a half-demolished building in the city of Wenling, in Zhejiang province, after a family that lives in the building refused to move. Luo Baogen and his wife, are embroiled in a row over the amount of relocation compensation offered by the government, and are the only remaining residents.
Property owners in China that refuse to move for new developments are known as 'Nail Householders', in a reference to a nail that is difficult to remove from wood. Laws in the People's Republic of China have recently been tightened up and it is now illegal to demolish a property without agreement.
Steve Clowney
(HT: Patrick S. O'Donnell)
November 26, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Carruthers & Skead on the Torrens System
Penny Carruthers (Wester Australia) and Natalie Skead (Western Australia) have posted 150 Years On: The Torrens Compensation Provisions in the ‘Last Resort’ Jurisdictions (Australian Property Law Journal) on SSRN. Here's the abstract:
One hundred and fifty years ago, with the introduction of the Torrens system into Australia, it was considered vital to incorporate compensation provisions into the Torrens legislation to enable a person sustaining loss through the operation of the system to obtain compensation from an assurance fund. Currently there are two broad compensation models operating in Australia. The ‘last resort’ model, adopted in the Australian Capital Territory; Western Australia; South Australia; and Tasmania, reflects the scheme of the compensation provisions as they were enacted 150 years ago. Under the last resort model, actions for compensation are, in most cases, to be brought initially against the ‘person liable’ for the deprivation. It is only in limited circumstances that access to the assurance fund may be available. The remaining jurisdictions have, in recent years, rejected the last resort model. In these ‘first resort’ jurisdictions a person deprived of an interest in land is entitled to bring an action, in the first instance, directly against the Registrar. The compensation provisions of the last resort jurisdictions are not uniform. The provisions are archaic, contradictory, confusing and have been described as a ‘tangled skein.’ The purpose of this article is to explore and clarify the operation of the compensation provisions of the last resort jurisdictions.
Steve Clowney
November 26, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Friday, November 23, 2012
The Interstate Highway System is Awesome
As millions of Americans contemplate the long journey home after the holiday, it's easy to forget that the interstate highway system is a real miracle:
In an article in the Review of Economics and Statistics in 1994, Ishaq Nadiri and Theofanis Mamuneas looked at the impact of the highway system. In all but three of the 35 industries they studied, costs fell sharply—by 24 cents for each $1 invested in the highways—thanks to easier and cheaper transport. As a result, the authors reckoned, the highway system had a big impact on productivity. During the late 1950s, they said, interstate-highway spending was responsible for 31% of the annual increase of American productivity (at a time when the economy was growing at 6% a year). Its contribution to productivity growth obviously slackened over time, but in the 1960s was still about 25%, before falling to 7% in the 1980s as the system neared completion.
Steve Clowney
November 23, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Tarrant on Obligations as Property
John Tarrant (Western Australia) has posted Obligations as Property (University of New South Wales Law Journal) on SSRN. Here's the abstract:
A widely asserted proposition is that all property rights are rights in rem and that rights in personam, such as debts and bank accounts, are not property rights. The proposition was advocated by John Austin based on his interpretation of Roman law. The obvious difficulty with the proposition is that it is irreconcilable with the case law because a number of cases from ultimate appellant courts confirm that debts are property rights. The author examines relevant case law and interpretations of Roman law to argue that the proposition that all property rights are rights in rem is based on a misunderstanding of Roman law. The author concludes that the assertion should be rejected as erroneous. Debts in the form of money obligations owed by one person to another are indeed property rights.
Steve Clowney
November 23, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (1) | TrackBack (0)
Thursday, November 22, 2012
Happy Thanksgiving!
In honor of the holiday, it's fun to recap the argument that private property saved the pilgrims. Benjamin Powell, an economist at Suffolk, tells the story here:
Many people believe that after suffering through a severe winter, the Pilgrims’ food shortages were resolved the following spring when the Native Americans taught them to plant corn and a Thanksgiving celebration resulted. In fact, the pilgrims continued to face chronic food shortages for three years until the harvest of 1623. Bad weather or lack of farming knowledge did not cause the pilgrims’ shortages. Bad economic incentives did.
In 1620 Plymouth Plantation was founded with a system of communal property rights. Food and supplies were held in common and then distributed based on equality and need as determined by Plantation officials. People received the same rations whether or not they contributed to producing the food, and residents were forbidden from producing their own food. . . . Because of the poor incentives, little food was produced.
Faced with potential starvation in the spring of 1623, the colony decided to implement a new economic system. Every family was assigned a private parcel of land. They could then keep all they grew for themselves, but now they alone were responsible for feeding themselves. This change, [the Pilgrims recorded], had very good success, for it made all hands very industrious, so as much more corn was planted than otherwise would have been. Giving people economic incentives changed their behavior. Once the Plymouth Plantation abandoned their communal economic system and adopted one with greater individual property rights, they never again faced the starvation and food shortages of the first three years.
This is a yarn that makes the property-lizard part of my brain start tingling. However, it doesn't really explain how the Indians managed to survive here for thousands and thousands of years.
Again, happy turkey day.
Steve Clowney
November 22, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Tuesday, November 20, 2012
Truly Disadvantaged Places
The Chronicle of Higher Education has published a lengthy article on William Julius Wilson and the effect of geography on a person's life outcomes:
Families that moved to safer and better-off areas "improved their health in ways that were quite profound," including reductions in obesity and diabetes, says Lawrence F. Katz, a Harvard economist who is principal investigator of the project's long-run study. They showed less depression, Katz says, and "very large increases in happiness." Yet the program failed to improve other key measures, like the earnings and employment rate of adults and the educational achievement of children.
Steve Clowney
November 20, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Rule on Property Rights and Energy
Troy Rule (Missouri) has posted Property Rights and Modern Energy (George Mason Law Review) on SSRN. Here's the abstract:
Property
law has evolved and adapted throughout its existence in response to
social and technological change. In this era of increasing focus on
sustainable energy, new property rights disputes arising from
innovations in the energy industry are once again stretching the bounds
of property law. As novel energy strategies spread across the country,
they are raising complex property questions involving wind currents,
sunlight, deep underground mineral deposits, airspace, subsurface pore
space, and other resources.
Resource governance regimes that
reflect the unique characteristics of emerging energy technologies can
play a valuable role in the nation’s continued pursuit of energy
sustainability. Unfortunately, despite volumes of legal scholarship on
the evolution and structuring of property rights regimes, there is
little consensus among lawmakers or within the legal academy regarding
how best to adapt such regimes to modern energy innovation. Courts and
legislatures are increasingly feeling pressure to alter long-established
property arrangements to accommodate and encourage new forms of energy
development. At what point do these adjustments go too far, excessively
compromising fairness and efficiency goals in an effort to promote a
new energy strategy?
This short article, written for a joint
program of the Natural Resources and Energy Law and Property Law
Sections of the American Association of Law Schools at the Association’s
2013 Annual Meeting, offers some general guidelines for adjusting
property rights regimes to accommodate new energy innovations. This
article suggests that, when feasible, policy actions that merely clarify
ambiguities in existing law are often the simplest and most
cost-effective way to respond when important technological advancements
place pressure on longstanding property structures. When such policies
are inadequate or unavailable, the most equitable and efficient
adjustments to property arrangements tend to be those that respect
rather than disregard property owners’ existing entitlements.
Steve Clowney
November 20, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Monday, November 19, 2012
How to Behave in Public Space
This weekend the NY Times ran a great piece about social norms and public space in the guise of a description of the quiet car on Amtrak. The punchline:
Respecting shared public space is becoming as quaintly archaic as tipping your hat to a lady, now that the concept of public space is as nearly extinct as hats, and ladies.
Steve Clowney
November 19, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
The Personal Property of Insane Asylum Patients
One of my favorite essays about property (which has been given wide circulation by the Perspectives on Property Law reader) is Erving Goffman's look that how patients in mental institutions carve out little domains of private property for themselves. Goffman shows how even in highly controlled societies, people define themselves by their claims over things and spaces. Last week the website, collectorsweekly.com, posted an fascinating piece that helps the public visualize the actual property of asylum patients. Both the piece and the accompanying photos are worth a gander:
If you were committed to a psychiatric institution, unsure if you’d ever return to the life you knew before, what would you take with you? That sobering question hovers like an apparition over each of the Willard Asylum suitcases. From the 1910s through the 1960s, many patients at the Willard Asylum for the Chronic Insane left suitcases behind when they passed away, with nobody to claim them. Upon the center’s closure in 1995, employees found hundreds of these time capsules stored in a locked attic. Working with the New York State Museum, former Willard staffers were able to preserve the hidden cache of luggage as part of the museum’s permanent collection.
Photographer Jon Crispin has long been drawn to the ghostly remains of abandoned psychiatric institutions. After learning of the Willard suitcases, Crispin sought the museum’s permission to document each case and its contents. In 2011, Crispin completed a successful Kickstarter campaign to help fund the first phase of the project, which he recently finished. Next spring, a selection of his photos will accompany the inaugural exhibit at the San Francisco Exploratorium’s new location.
Steve Clowney
November 19, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Arnold & Gunderson on the Management of Natural Resources
Tony Arnold (Louisville) and Lance Gunderson (Emory) have posted Adaptive Law (Book Chapter) on SSRN. here's the abstract:
This book chapter proposes a bold sweeping set of characteristics of "adaptive law": features of the legal system that promote the resilience and adaptive capacity of both social systems and ecosystems. Law, particularly U.S. law, has been characterized as ill-suited to management of natural resources and the environment for resilience and sustainability. The maladaptive features of U.S. law include narrow systemic goals, mononcentric, unimodal, and fragmented structure, inflexible methods, and rational, linear, legal-centralist processes. This book chapter proposes four fundamental features of an adaptive legal system: 1) multiplicty of articulated goals; 2) polycentric, multimodal, and integrationist structure; 3) adaptive methods based on standards, flexibility, discretion, and regard for context; and 4) iterative legal-pluralist proceses with feedback loops and accountability. It then discusses these four features in the context of several socio-ecological issues and identifies needs for future study and development of adaptive law, particularly in light of panarchy theory about how complex, adaptive, interconnected systems change over time.
Steve Clowney
November 19, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)