Tuesday, March 20, 2012

A Portrait of the World's Possessions

Photojournalist Peter Menzel's Material World may be of interest to PropertyProfs.  "In each of the 30 countries, Menzel found a statistically average family and photographed them outside their home, with all of their belongings. The result is an incredible cross-cultural quilt of possessions, from the utilitarian to the sentimental, revealing the faceted and varied ways in which we use “stuff” to make sense of the world and our place in it."  Check out some of the pictures here.

Steve Clowney

March 20, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

An Inside Look at New York's Most Exclusive Address

 

Building

The N.Y. Times runs a profile of 15 Central Park West - Manhattan's most expensive luxury building:

 

After descending to the lobby on a recent Saturday, we walked past three gas-burning fireplaces on the way to the library, which had dozens of books and several comfy chairs. The dining room was closed (it isn’t open on weekends), but Ms. Baekgaard assured me that “it is the best place to eat in the city.” There is no dress code; some residents wear shorts to lunch, she said.

Steve Clowney

 

 Update:  Link fixed

March 20, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Reiss on Dodd-Frank's 'Qualified Mortgage'

Reiss_david
David Reiss (Brooklyn) has posted Message in a Mortgage: What Dodd-Frank's 'Qualified Mortgage' Tells Us About Ourselves (Boston U. Review of Banking and Financial Law).  Here's the abstract:

This essay outlines the ethics that shape federal housing finance policy and situates them in the context of the Dodd-Frank Act. In a way, however, it asks a simpler question: what do our mortgages tell us about our society? The essay proceeds as follows. First, it outlines three ethics that inform American housing finance policy generally. Second, it contrasts two mortgages: the one from the subprime boom of the early 2000s and the other from Dodd-Frank, the “Qualified Mortgage.” It concludes by using the three ethics to answer the question posed above and outlining what is at stake in the housing sector given the choices that we might make.

Steve Clowney

March 20, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Monday, March 19, 2012

The Enforcement of Property Claims

Eduardo Penalver has a intriguing post about the difficulty of enforcing small property claims:

I've been thinking about small claims, becuase in the property context they are pervasive and pose a real challenge but for some reason don't get much attention.  

First off, let me explain why I think small (and even medium-sized) claims pose a particular problem in the property context.  (I'm not making a strong claim, here, and I don't think much hangs on the idea that this is a problem unique to property.  So please forgive me if you think I'm way off base on this.)  

The biggest reason is that the class action mechanism is usually not available for property disputes.  Small and medium-sized property disputes, especially land conflicts, tend to be relatively small-n affairs, and the facts of each case are usually sufficiently distinct that even litgiation against a repeat player (e.g., a large landlord) may not justify class treatment.

The whole thing is worth your time.

Steve Clowney

March 19, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Is There Anything That Can't be Bought?

Over at The Atlantic, Harvard philosophy professor Michael Sandel looks at the hidden costs of the "market thinking" that permeates our society:

While it is certainly true that greed played a role in the financial crisis, something bigger was and is at stake. The most fateful change that unfolded during the past three decades was not an increase in greed. It was the reach of markets, and of market values, into spheres of life traditionally governed by nonmarket norms. To contend with this condition, we need to do more than inveigh against greed; we need to have a public debate about where markets belong—and where they don’t.

Steve Clowney

March 19, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Render on the Law of the Body

Render
Meredith Render (Alabama) has posted The Law of the Body (Emory Law Journal) on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

This article posits that a “law of the body” is overdue. In the absence of clarity about the legal status of the human body, courts have constructed a collection of circumstantially-defined categories for resolving question of human body ownership and use. This patchwork approach is awkward, unwieldy, incoherent, and, by many lights, ultimately unjust. Many able minds have been applied to critiquing the distributive consequences of a regime in which we cannot – at any point in our lives – “own” our own bodies (or its constituent parts), but other people can and do. But what has been missing from these conversations is a conceptual foundation for understanding the living human body as property. This article supplies that piece of this byzantine puzzle. Specifically, the thesis presented here holds that by employing a property framework to understanding the legal status of the human body we can explain with coherence and consilience our existing legal commitments concerning the treatment of the human body.

Moreover, the article addresses the standard objections to explicitly acknowledging the human body as an object of property and demonstrates that these objections are predicated on a series of misunderstandings. These misunderstandings generally fall into three categories: misunderstandings about the nature of “property;” conceptual misunderstandings about bodies and selves and the capacity to own oneself; and misunderstandings about the necessary consequences of adopting a property framework with respect to the human body. Once these misapprehensions are clarified, the intellectual path will be cleared for a “law of the body” to emerge, and legislators, courts, and scholars can begin the important work of shaping it into a doctrine that is consistent with our normative ends.

Steve Clowney

March 19, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, March 16, 2012

Will the Supreme Court Kill Rent Control?, Ctd.

Over that Volokh, Ilya Somin follows up on a potentially important takings case that the Supreme Court may decide to hear:

When I first heard about this case, my reaction was that it was probably precluded by the Supreme Court’s 1992 decision in Yee v. Escondido, which ruled that a California statute imposing rent control on mobile home parks was not a taking, even though state law allowed tenants to renew the rent-controlled leases indefinitely even against the will of the owners. I am no fan of the Yee decision, but the Court is unlikely to overrule it in the near future.

However, there is a crucial difference between Harmon’s case and Yee. In the latter, the Court emphasized that there was no permanent physical occupation of the owners’ property because “the Mobilehome Residency Law provides that a park owner who wishes to change the use of his land may evict his tenants” so long as he then uses the property for something other than a mobile home park. By contrast, as Root describes, the New York City rent control law does not allow Harmon and other landlords to evict their tenants even if they do wish to use the property for something other than rental housing. Effectively, therefore, this is a government-imposed permanent physical occupation of property.

Steve Clowney

March 16, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (1) | TrackBack (0)

Chang & Smith on Civil Law v. Common Law Property

Henry Smith (Harvard) and Yun-chien Chang (Academia Sinica - Taiwan) have posted An Economic Analysis of Civil versus Common Law Property (Notre Dame Law Review) on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

Common law and civil law property appear to be quite different, with the former emphasizing pieces of ownership called estates and the latter focusing on holistic ownership. And yet the two systems are remarkably similar in their broad outlines, for functional reasons. This paper offers a transaction cost explanation for the practical similarity and the differing styles of delineating property and ownership in the two systems. As opposed to the “complete” property system that could obtain in the world of zero transaction costs, actual property systems employ structures characterized by shortcuts in order to achieve property’s substantive goals of protecting interests in use. Overlooking this structure leads to the bundle of rights picture of property, even though property is a structured bundle of relationships. The architecture of property consists in part of four basic relationships, and a number of characteristic features of property automatically arise out this architecture, including exclusion rights, in rem status, and running to successors. Where civil law and common law differ is in their style of delineation, which reflects the path dependence of initial investment in feudal fragmentation in the common law and Roman-inspired holistic dominion in civil law. This transaction cost explanation for the functional similarities but different delineation process in the two systems promises to put the comparative law of property on a sounder descriptive footing.

Steve Clowney

March 16, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Thursday, March 15, 2012

Rule on Airspace and the Takings Clause

Troy A. Rule (Missouri) has posted Airspace and the Takings Clause on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

This Article argues that the U.S. Supreme Court’s takings jurisprudence fails to account for instances when public entities restrict private airspace solely to keep it open for their own use. Many landowners rely on open space above adjacent land to preserve scenic views for their properties, to provide sunlight access for their rooftop solar panels, or to serve other uses that require no physical invasion of the neighboring space. Private citizens typically must purchase easements or covenants to prevent their neighbors from erecting trees or buildings that would interfere with these non-physical airspace uses. In contrast, public entities can often secure their non-physical uses of neighboring airspace without having to compensate neighbors by simply imposing height restrictions or other regulations on the space. The Supreme Court’s existing regulatory takings rules, which focus heavily on whether a challenged government action involves physical invasion of the claimant’s property or destroys all economically beneficial use of the property, fail to protect private landowners against these uncompensated takings of negative airspace easements. In recent years, regulations aimed at keeping private airspace open for specific government uses have threatened wind energy developments throughout the country and have even halted major construction projects near the Las Vegas Strip. This Article highlights several situations in which governments can impose height restrictions or other regulations as a way to effectively take negative airspace easements for their own benefit. The Article describes why current regulatory takings rules fail to adequately protect citizens against these situations and advocates a new rule capable of filling this gap in takings law. The new rule would clarify the Supreme Court’s takings jurisprudence as it relates to airspace and would promote more fair and efficient allocations of airspace rights between governments and private citizens.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there may be some delay in posting]

March 15, 2012 in Recent Scholarship, Takings | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Occupy New Haven

Newhavengreen

A story from New Haven about Occupy Movement and its clash with the quasi-private ownership structure of the of the Town Green:

Its members have officially owned the Green and chosen their successors since the early 17th century. The group began with the original settlers of New Haven Colony. The state legislature affirmed their descendants’ legal right to control the Green in 1683, then again in 1723. (Read more about that history here.) . . . .Pattis’ complaint charges that the group’s very existence and its ownership of the Green violate the state constitution.

Steve Clowney

(HT: Will Baude)

March 15, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Stahl on Local Governments and the "One Person/One Vote" Rule

Stahl
Ken Stahl (Chapman) has posted Local Government, One Person/One Vote, and the Jewish Question on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

This article argues that the Supreme Court’s jurisprudence regarding the application of the 'one person/one vote' rule to local governments, while often considered hopelessly confused, actually contains an internal logic that reflects the ambiguous legacy of the Enlightenment in this country. There are three broad strands within the one person/one vote jurisprudence: the first, beginning with Avery v. Midland County, requires cities to apportion votes based on a 'one person/one vote' principle; the second, exemplified by Ball v. James, permits certain municipalities to apportion votes according to a 'one dollar/one vote' formula; and a third, captured in Holt Civic Club v. City of Tuscaloosa, gives the state plenary power to allocate votes with regard to some local government matters. Although these three strands seem impossible to reconcile, they are all consistent with an Enlightenment jurisprudential project to consolidate the power of the central state by suppressing the ability of entities exercising authority over particular territories, such as local governments, to challenge the state’s hegemony. Each line of cases accomplishes this end by creating an idealized standard for political participation that conceptualizes voters as abstract, homogenous individuals who are divorced from their parochial territorial commitments and thus capable of being acted upon by the state without regard to such commitments.

The article further reveals, however, that the evisceration of territory in these cases is actually an illusion. Under the guise that territory has been rendered immaterial, the courts surreptitiously permit local governments to exercise a substantial degree of territorial control. For example, in the case of City of Eastlake v. Forest City Enterprises, the Court upheld a tiny suburban municipality’s parochial exercise of the zoning power (excluding an affordable housing complex) by invoking the municipality’s subjection to the one person/one vote rule. Because one person/one vote purports to remove territorial affiliations from the political realm, it had the power in East lake to transform a small fragment of a large metropolitan region into 'the people,' a despatialized abstraction that was entitled, by virtue of its ostensible remove from territorial particularity, to exercise the zoning power in its own interest.

I explain the ambiguous use of territory in the jurisprudence by drawing upon the Enlightenment obsession with 'the Jewish question,' or the problem of incorporating territorially-bound subgroups like the Jewish ghetto into a modern nation-state predicated on the idea of a uniform citizenry. The tension between the surface homogenization and the underlying fragmentation of territory in the one person/one vote cases reflects an uneasy compromise between the Enlightenment attempt to incorporate groups such as the Jews into the abstract 'rights of man' and a pragmatic realization that territorial sovereignty is a precondition to securing human rights. This compromise, I argue, has troubling consequences: it enables those with sufficient political or financial power to retreat into insulated enclaves under the aegis of state neutrality, while foreclosing recompense for those excluded from such enclaves by deploying the fiction that they still retain their abstract rights. The article concludes accordingly that the egalitarian promise of the one person/one vote jurisprudence rings hollow.

Steve Clowney

March 15, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Wednesday, March 14, 2012

The Rent is Too Damn High, Ctd.

Matt Yglesias, blogger extraordinaire, has recently published a short e-book that examines land use and urban policy issues.  Although Yglesias is a self-described lefty on many issues, he makes a strong push for less land use regulation.  Here's a clip of his bloggingheads discussion with Robert Wright:

Also, if any legal academic wants to do a short book review of this piece, get in touch with me.  I promise to post the whole thing on the website.

Steve Clowney

March 14, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (1) | TrackBack (0)

Claeys on the Bundle of Sticks

Claeys_eric
Eric Claeys (George Mason) has posted Bundle-of-Sticks Notions in Legal and Economic Scholarship (Econ J. Watch) on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

The phrase “bundle of rights” does not serve as an accurate conceptual definition of property. Nor has that phrase provided a helpful metaphor as used in Ronald Coase’s article “The Problem of Social Cost” (1960) and subsequent legal and economic scholarship. Coase’s usage portrays property rights as a collection of individualized permissions to use an asset, when in sound conceptual usage “property” signifies a domain of authority to decide how to use the asset. The “bundle” metaphor may be understood to state that an owner has a right to deploy his property in any specific manner fairly implied by his general rights of ownership. Although this metaphorical usage is helpful, it remains parasitic on a sound conceptual definition of property. Property is best conceived of as a right securing a normative interest in determining exclusively the use of an asset external to the person of the owner.

Steve Clowney

March 14, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Tuesday, March 13, 2012

The Worlds Most Outstanding Staircases

Slate runs a slideshow of the world's most unique staircases.

Picture 5


Steve Clowney

(Photo: Wilfried-Dechau.de)

March 13, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Rosser on Progressive Property

Rosser

Ezra Rosser (American) has posted The Ambition and Transformative Potential of Progressive Property  (California Law Review / Berkeley) on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

The emerging progressive property school of thought champions and finds its meaning in the social nature of property. Rejecting the idea that exclusion lies at the core of property law, progressive property scholars call for a reconsideration of the relationships owners and non-owners have with property and with each other. Despite these ambitions, so far progressive property scholarship has largely confined itself to questions of exclusion and access. This paper argues that such an emphasis glosses over the race-related acquisition and distribution problems that plague American history and property law. The modest structural changes supported by progressive property scholars fail to account for this racial history and, by so doing, present a limited vision of the changes to property law that progressive scholars should support. Though sympathetic with the progressive property political and scholarly orientation and the policy arguments made regarding exclusion and access, I argue that the first priority of any transformative project of progressive property must be revisiting acquisition and distribution.

Steve Clowney

March 13, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Monday, March 12, 2012

The Art of Auction Valuation

The Economist runs an eye-catching story on the art of valuing property in high end auction houses.  The piece traces a controversy over a six-foot long gold chain that allegedly belonged to Henry VIII:

Lord Coleridge claimed that the auction-house expert, Elizabeth Mitchell, was negligent when she gave an auction valuation of a treasured family heirloom. The historic gold chain of office had been in his family for generations, and the Coleridges (distant relatives of the poet Samuel Taylor Coleridge) believed it dated from the mid-16th century. Lord Coleridge had expected that the estimate for his rare Tudor jewel would be £500,000 or more. Ms Mitchell, however, proposed that it was from the late 17th century, and gave it an estimate of £25,000 to £35,000. This, Lord Coleridge claimed, had cost him a good deal of money. He sued for £415,000.

Steve Clowney

March 12, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Fourteen-Year-Old Buys House. Has the Market Bottomed Out ?

NPR profiles Willow Tufano, a 14-year-old Floridian who recently purchased a rental property for $12,000.  Is this: (a) a sign of the apocalypse, or (b) a sign that the housing market has finally hit bottom?

Steve Clowney

March 12, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Miller on Building Legal Neighborhoods

Stephen-Miller

Stephen Miller (Idaho) has posted Building Legal Neighborhoods (Harvard Envtl Law Rev) on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

Political and legal tools have emerged since the Seventies, and especially in the last two decades, that provide political and legal power to neighborhoods. However, these tools are often used in an ad hoc fashion and there has been scant analysis of how these tools might work together effectively. This article seeks to explore this trend, and further argues that cities consciously overlay these neighborhood legal tools. This approach is referred to in the article as a de facto “legal neighborhood.” This approach does not call for secession of neighborhoods from cities or for the wholesale privatization of public functions, as have others that argue for neighborhood empowerment. Rather, the article asserts that the collective operation of these neighborhood tools is greater than the sum of their parts, providing a method for civic engagement at a level city-wide politicians feel comfortable serving and in which residents feel comfortable participating. The article also provides approaches for linking the neighborhood to city and regional affairs, and a history and theory of the concept of the neighborhood as an argument for the important role and function of neighborhoods in American life.

Steve Clowney

March 12, 2012 in Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, March 9, 2012

Law Students Hanging Up Your Own Shingle: Want to Make Money and Do Good?

1.  Get a list of power-of-sale foreclosures conducted in your area in the past 5 years.

2.  Examine the record for that property at your local county recording office.

3.  See whether or not the foreclosing party had the legal right to foreclose (HINT:  Chances are very good they didn't). 

4.  Contact the former owner of the property, who probably did not contest the foreclosure since she couldn't afford an attorney, and inform her that she has been unlawfully harmed.

5.  Ask her if she would like to bring suit against the foreclosing party for wrongful foreclosure and and infliction of emotional distress.

6.  Go get them.

7.  Repeat step 6.

8.  Repeat steps 1 through 7.

When the criminal law fails to deter unlawful behavior, the civil law should step in.  You can make a good living as a lawyer in a difficult economy and do good for society. 

You don't have to seek restitution of the foreclosed upon property if the client doesn't want it; damages are enough for justice.

 

Mark A. Edwards

 

 

March 9, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Where Seniors Live & Where They Are Moving

In the United States, it's fairly well-known that the population of individuals over the age of 65 is exploding.  One less reported aspect of that story is the wide variation in the rate of growth of the senior population at the state and local level.  Urbanland has a story on where seniors currently live, where they're headed, and how these decisions will impact communities:

Seniors benefit communities as well as present them with challenges. For instance, seniors are wealthier than any other age group . . . . They also are more politically conservative, and what they want in and need from a community is often quite different from what young families want and need.  . . .  Seniors are, for instance, pushing for more parks, open space, and libraries, often at the expense of funds for schools and playgrounds.

Steve Clowney

March 9, 2012 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)