Tuesday, June 16, 2020
Guest Post by Charles Calleros, Talking about Race in the Contracts Course: Interface with Civil Rights Laws, Part II – Consideration
In my previous post, I outlined the background for 42 U.S.C § 1981, the Reconstruction Era statute providing that “[a]ll persons . . . shall have the right to make and enforce contracts . . . as is enjoyed by White citizens.” The common law of mutual assent permitted racial discrimination in offer and acceptance, necessitating corrective legislation. But section 1981 imposes liability only if the defendant thwarted an attempt to “make” a contract, which requirement is not satisfied if someone is harassed for “shopping while Black” to the point of leaving the store before trying to make a purchase. The majority and dissent in Gregory v. Dillard’s, Inc., 565 F.3d 464 (8th Cir. 2009), discuss this issue in detail.
In another case applying section 1981, the court analyzed a different element of contract formation: consideration. Barfield v. Commerce Bank, N.A., 484 F.3d 1276 (2007). Thwarting mutual assent was not in question because Barfield, a Black man, entered a bank and offered to exchange his large bill for smaller bills. The bank refused this service on the pretext that Barfield did not have an account with the bank, a requirement not imposed on White passersby who asked to change a large bill. The court describes how Barfield confirmed the bank’s discriminatory policy by running tests with his father, a White friend, and a White reporter.
Notwithstanding this proof, the court could not apply section 1981 unless Barfield was offering to make a “contract,” which would require consideration. The element of consideration in question, it seems, was reciprocal inducement, specifically whether the bank was induced or whether the bank was simply performing a gratuitous service. Barfield was certainly induced by the prospect of giving up a large bill in exchange for the equivalent in several smaller bills, which are easier to use in most transactions. But was the bank induced to give up smaller bills in exchange for a large one from someone not holding an account? Although the court does not discuss this, is it possible that ending up with fewer, larger bills at the end of the day makes for easier storage and accounting? The court adopts a more interesting explanation: the bank is induced by the prospect that some non-account-holders, stopping initially only to get change, will be impressed with the bank and decide to open accounts and pay the accompanying fees. The Bank apparently didn’t have the nerve to argue that the prospect of attracting Black customers did not provide the same inducement as did foot traffic by White customers, and the court found it unnecessary to parse inducement to that degree. If not for Barfield’s race, Barfield’s offer would have resulted in a contract.
I like to teach Barfield for several reasons:
- It is short – much shorter than Gregory v. Dillard’s – and thus easily assigned and discussed.
- It reveals racial discrimination in what should be a common, perfunctory transaction. (How many times have we heard a shopkeeper, when asked to change a bill, respond, “We’re not a bank,” as though a bank is indisputably the right place to get change?).
- The racial discrimination appears in a legal context – consideration – that infrequently addresses race and thus injects some additional relevance to our study of that arcane subject.
- The racial discrimination is so clearly confirmed by Barfield and so explicitly set forth in the opinion that one does not need additional materials or inference to find racial discrimination.
- The case is relatively recent, so the discrimination cannot be dismissed by any student as a relic of the past but is a reminder of persistent and pervasive discrimination in our society, from commercial dealings to criminal justice.
https://lawprofessors.typepad.com/contractsprof_blog/2020/06/guest-post-by-charles-calleros-talking-about-race-in-the-contracts-course-interface-with-civil-right-1.html
Comments
I agree that the situation is better understood as a simultaneous exchange that does not trigger contracts law. Hence your argument that banks should be treated as public utilities would be an important supplement to the common law. But until your idea is accepted, I don't see how we get to the just result without an attenuated theory of consideration.
The theory of consideration seems to run something like this -- the bank provides a service that induces foot traffic in order to attract potential account holders. Mr. Barfield is not Williston's tramp; he is giving good consideration by stepping into the store and accepting the bank's offer of services by producing a large bill for exchange.
So isn't this an occasion to pat our friend consideration on the back and say "Two cheers for you, old chum!"?
Posted by: Jeremy Telman | Jul 13, 2020 6:09:57 AM
Arizona is one state with a broad public accommodations law that covers all types of businesses, including banks, but recourse consists of filing a complaint with the State AG's Office of Civil Rights, which apparently is the entity that can take some sort of administrative or legal action, and I'm not sure that a victim of discrimination has a private right of action. So, section 1981 might be the only private right of action in many states. Is this an example of a court leaning toward finding a contract so that the discrimination law can apply? Maybe, but once it adopts the framework of contract, the consideration analysis itself is no stretch and indeed is similar to a case where foot traffic into a casino was an inducement for a casino's allowing a free pull of a giant slot machine. So, the consideration analysis itself is not attenuated, but Alan raises a good question about whether it's a contract that requires consideration in the first place. To take off from Alan's parenthetic, even if it is viewed as a simultaneous exchange, couldn't we find that each is warranting his/her bill to be authentic legal tender so that the exchange would be a contract? (BTW, that question arises in a simulation that I run in the first hour of my course). As an aside, I do like your idea about regulating banks as public utilities.
Posted by: Charles R Calleros | Jul 14, 2020 11:31:37 AM
Consideration doctrine is unnecessary in Barfield, as in many cases that recite it. A contract is fundamentally a promise whose breach can result in invoking the power of the state; there is no more contract in a simultaneous exchange of currency than in a simultaneous exchange of currency for produce at a market (assuming no warranties or other future commitments.) If the exchange includes any implied warranties (for example of non-counterfeit) then Mr. Barfield's implied promise is clearly a contract, either based on exchange or reliance.
The racism at issue here is a public accommodation issue, unfortunately not reached by federal antidiscrimination law but covered by many state laws. I have argued elsewhere that banks ought to be treated as public utilities providing universal service at fair prices to all, but that is another matter.
Posted by: Alan White | Jul 12, 2020 12:51:32 AM