Friday, April 30, 2021

How to Choose the Lesser Evil When Defining Local Markets?

In the Greek mythology, Odysseus famously lost six companions after he chose to sail towards Scylla, while escaping from an even worse venture if he had gone towards Charybdis. Economists often weigh the pros and cons of different alternatives, none of which is ideal (or first best in economic jargon). This paper discusses one of such choices: whether to define local markets by relying on catchment areas or by applying a hypothetical monopoly test. It argues that competition authorities should recognise more explicitly that this choice should be driven by the quality of the available data.

April 30, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

THE ANTITRUST CASE AGAINST THE APPLE APP STORE

 
ABSTRACT

The Apple App Store is the only channel through which app developers may distribute their apps on iOS. First launched in 2008, the App Store has evolved into a highly profitable marketplace, with overall consumer spend exceeding $50 billion in 2019. However, concerns are being increasingly expressed on both sides of the Atlantic that various practices of Apple with regard to the App Store may breach competition law. The purpose of this paper is to examine whether this is indeed the case and, if so, how these concerns can be addressed. With these aims in mind, the paper first introduces the reader to the app ecosystem and the Apple App Store, with a focus on Apple’s in-app payment policies and the 30 percent commission charged for in-app purchases. After engaging critically with the distinction between apps selling “digital” and apps selling “physical” goods or services, we consider such distinction is unclear, artificial, and unprincipled.

The paper then critically reviews several practices of Apple that appear to be at odds with competition law and in particular Article 102 TFEU. We first analyze the issue of market definition and dominance with regard to the App Store. We find that Apple is a monopolist in the market for app distribution on iOS, as it is not subject to any meaningful competitive constraint from alternative distribution channels, such as Android app stores. The result is that Apple is the gateway through which app developers have to go to reach the valuable audience of iOS users. This bottleneck position affords Apple the power to engage in several prima facie anticompetitive practices. A first concern is that Apple may exploit app developers by charging excessive fees for the services it provides and by imposing unfair trading conditions. Second, based on four case studies, the paper illustrates how Apple may use its control of the App Store or iOS to engage in exclusionary behavior to the detriment of rival apps. These practices should be investigated by competition authorities, as they are likely to result in considerable consumer harm, be it in the form of higher app prices, worse user experience or reduced consumer choice. The paper finally proposes a combination of concrete remedies that would address the competition concerns identified.

April 30, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Thursday, April 29, 2021

Regulation of Data-driven Market Power in the Digital Economy: Business Value Creation and Competitive Advantages from Big Data

Regulation of Data-driven Market Power in the Digital Economy: Business Value Creation and Competitive Advantages from Big Data

Victoria Fast

University of Passau

Daniel Schnurr

University of Passau

Michael Wohlfarth

University of Passau

Abstract

Recent high-profile antitrust cases and policy proposals have put a spotlight on the relationship between firms’ access to big data and sustained competitive advantages in digital markets. In Europe, concerns about data-driven market power have led policy makers to propose far-reaching regulations of information technology (IT) in these markets. Despite the global policy relevance, the regulation of big data and its competitive effects has so far received little attention in information systems (IS) research. This article addresses this research gap and makes a three-fold contribution. First, we review the academic literature and show that there is extensive, although nuanced, empirical evidence for business value creation from big (user) data. Second, we draw on the resource-based view of the firm and recent policy reports to derive six facilitating factors that enable firms to establish market power based on sustained data-driven competitive advantages. Third, we characterize three regulatory approaches to govern market power and competition in data-driven digital markets: (i) empowering consumers, (ii) data openness and (iii) limiting data scale. For each of these approaches, we highlight the key role of IT artifacts in mediating the effect of regulatory rules on actual practice and thus point to promising opportunities for future IS research.

April 29, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Big Tech, Big Data, And Competition Policy: Favoring Dynamic Over Static Competition

Big Tech, Big Data, And Competition Policy: Favoring Dynamic Over Static Competition

Nicolas Petit

European University Institute - Department of Law (LAW)

David Teece

Institute for Business Innovation

Abstract

This paper gives a fresh account of competition in the digital economy. Our understanding is that usual static monopoly narratives paint with too broad a brush. We suggest that some leading firms in the digital economy have strong dynamic capabilities, and they are not durable monopolists. A few strategic errors by management and they are deeply impaired. We derive the theoretical implications of this, and outline what’s required to advance a deeper understanding of the digital economy. We look at policy and provide a normative formulation of the competitive process, highlighting dynamic competition and distinguishing it from static competition. We consider the economics of big data and big data management and explore how strong dynamic capabilities are necessary for Big Tech companies to get ahead and stay ahead. We explore different types of economic rent, suggest a modified welfare standard for competition policy, and formulate preliminary tests and predictors to measure dynamic competition.

April 29, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Double Marginalization and Vertical Integration

Double Marginalization and Vertical Integration

 

Philippe Choné

National Institute of Statistics and Economic Studies (INSEE) - Center for Research in Economics and Statistics (CREST); CESifo (Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute)

Laurent Linnemer

National Institute of Statistics and Economic Studies (INSEE) - Center for Research in Economics and Statistics (CREST)

Thibaud Vergé

National Institute of Statistics and Economic Studies (INSEE) - Center for Research in Economics and Statistics (CREST)

Abstract

Asymmetric information in procurement entails double marginalization. The phenomenon is most severe when the buyer has all the bargaining power at the production stage, while it vanishes when the buyer and suppliers’ weights are balanced. Vertical integration eliminates double marginalization and reduces the likelihood that the buyer purchases from independent suppliers. Conditional on market foreclosure, the probability that final consumers are harmed is positive only if the buyer has more bargaining power when selecting suppliers than when negotiating over quantities and intermediate prices. The buyer’s and consumers’ interests are otherwise aligned.

April 29, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Dynamic Vertical Foreclosure

Dynamic Vertical Foreclosure

April 29, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Wednesday, April 28, 2021

Competition Law and Digital Ecosystems: Learning To Walk Before We Run

Competition Law and Digital Ecosystems: Learning To Walk Before We Run

Frederic Jenny

ESSEC Business School

Abstract

Competition authorities are under severe political pressure to intervene quickly against the digital behemoth for a variety of reasons. Various expert reports have suggested that traditional antitrust or competition law enforcement and merger control are inadequate or insufficient to deal with competition issues in the digital sector. In this paper we review a number of issues for which further economic thinking is required before competition authorities can make informed and relevant decisions about competition on digital markets.

We review the difference between competition between firms and competition between digital multi-products ecosystems, data and privacy issues, the relationship between competition within ecosystems and competition between ecosystems, the implications of consumer biases on competition in the digital sector, the competition issues raised by gatekeepers, and the trade-offs involved in interoperability and data portability. We also discuss merger control. We conclude with a research agenda to help competition authorities avoid the risks of inadvertently giving in to the political pressure of economic populism or ideology or issuing misguided decisions which may be ineffective or, even worse, restrict competition or innovation in the digital sector

April 28, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Vertical Mergers and Input Foreclosure: Lessons from the AT&T/Time Warner Case

Vertical Mergers and Input Foreclosure: Lessons from the AT&T/Time Warner Case

Carl Shapiro

University of California, Berkeley - Haas School of Business

Abstract

This article offers a practical guide to analyzing vertical mergers using the general approach to input foreclosure and raising rivals’ costs described in the 2020 Vertical Merger Guidelines issued by the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission. The step-by-step analysis described here draws lessons from how that theory of harm played out in the lone vertical merger case litigated by the antitrust agencies in recent decades, namely the 2018 challenge by the Department of Justice to the merger between AT&T and Time Warner. I testified in court as the DOJ’s economic expert in that case, giving me a unique perspective. I explain here how to quantify the increase in rivals’ costs and the elimination of double marginalization caused by a vertical merger and how to evaluate their net effect on downstream customers. I also explain how this economic analysis fits into the three-step burden-shifting approach that the courts apply to mergers under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. Based on my experience in the AT&T/Time Warner case, I identify a number of shortcomings of the 2020 Vertical Merger Guidelines.

April 28, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Does Market Power Encourage or Discourage Investment? Evidence from the Hospital Market

Does Market Power Encourage or Discourage Investment? Evidence from the Hospital Market

April 28, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

What Does an Appreciable Negative Effect on Competition Mean?

What Does an Appreciable Negative Effect on Competition Mean?

Christian Bergqvist

University of Copenhagen - Faculty of Law

Abstract

Throughout the years, much intellectual energy has been invested into drawing the line between being anti-competitive by object or by effect, ignoring that an infringement must also be appreciable. Most likely based on a presumption that this is no longer a separate requirement, but part of analyzing the former. However, case law does not render full support for this, thus making it necessary to revisit the issue of being appreciable as a potential separate requirement.

April 28, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Tuesday, April 27, 2021

A New Era for Antitrust Market Definition

A New Era for Antitrust Market Definition

 

Viktoria H.S.E. Robertson

University of Graz; Vienna University of Economics and Business

Abstract

A new era is dawning for market definition under EU competition law. It is being rung in by five distinct developments that, together, foreshadow the future of the relevant market as a tool of competition law. A plethora of policy reports on digital markets have made recommendations for antitrust market definition, while an increasing body of case law is tackling new issues arising for market definition. The European Commission is updating its Market Definition Notice to make it fit for current market realities, while also treading new paths with its forthcoming market investigation tool. In addition, the academic debate is exploring different avenues for recalibrating market definition. By analyzing these developments, the contribution explores what may lie in store for the relevant market as a fundamental analytical tool of EU competition law.

April 27, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Competition Law, Climate Change and Sustainability

Competition Law, Climate Change and Sustainability

 

Suzanne Kingston

Sutherland School of Law, University College Dublin

Abstract

Should competition law prohibit competitors from agreeing to produce more energy-efficient goods, where this means higher prices for consumers? Is a dominant undertaking that switches to using only pricier recyclable packaging abusing its dominant position? Can the fact that a merger may lead to lower carbon emissions from production in the long-term be taken into account by competition authorities? Should state aid to coal-fired power plants be permitted?

April 27, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

The Role of Transnational Legal Process in Enforcing WTO Law and Competition Policy

The Role of Transnational Legal Process in Enforcing WTO Law and Competition Policy

 

Weimin Shen

Washington University School of Law

Abstract

This Article creates a paradigm for future studies of the role of Transnational Legal Process in the field of the interface between trade and competition policy to enhance a legal-based trade relationship between countries. It suggests that essential synergies that exist between trade and competition. In examining cartel issues both under WTO treaty obligations and under antitrust laws, Transnational Legal Process will largely prove a positive role in constraining the opportunities for States to play one system (trade) against the other (competition). I explore several recent U.S. antitrust litigations involving Chinese export cartels. I also examine the relationship between trade associations and the government under the hybrid nature of China’s regulatory environment. I argue that the involved U.S. courts and the executive branch’s stance in the above litigations perfectly illustrates a pervasive Transnational Legal Process. The courts and the executive branch as transnational actors stimulate each other to avert gaming by the litigants due to ambiguous factual evidence in cartel cases. In this context, the U.S. not only represents all antitrust nations’ interests when it is anti-cartel. The transnational actors generated interactions that led to WTO law and competition policy interpretations that become internalized, thereby binding under domestic law.

April 27, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

The Faux Pas in Modern Competition Law – Walled Gardens, Data Sharing and Algorithmic Decision Making

The Faux Pas in Modern Competition Law – Walled Gardens, Data Sharing and Algorithmic Decision Making

Cambridge Law Review (De Lege Ferenda), Volume III (Forthcoming)

Kan Jie Marcus Ho

University of Cambridge, Faculty of Law

Date Written: February 13, 2021

Abstract

The milieu of the 21st century has triggered a wave of unprecedented changes across traditional market structures, igniting disruption and necessitating evolution in firms big and small.

A brief survey of the current global climate reveals the digital economy largely requiring some form of intervention – lest market abuse arise to the detriment of the modern consumer. In the United States, the Gordian Knot of walled gardens in the social media industry has triggered antitrust attention; where ‘Google’ and ‘Facebook’, juggernauts of the social media industry, have largely created a confined duopoly system. Indeed, the ability for said companies to access much sought-after consumer data, led to regulation being necessary to prevent market abuse.

Winging this issue to the United Kingdom and the European Union, technological developments have led to a necessary change in regulations – to facilitate innovation, while at the same time to ensure adequate consumer protection. This paper will adopt a two-pronged approach – in the first part, an economics-focused view will be adopted to examine the present digital economy; and in the second - the current regime in the UK will be analysed from a legal perspective, focusing on how Art 101 TFEU and Chapter I of the UK Competition Act affects firms from a top-down level. The final scope of this argument contrasts the Bundeskartellamt’s investigation into Facebook with AGCM’s investigation in Italy, fully fleshing out the regulatory dilemmas encountered by competition authorities of the region. In the final analysis, this paper argues that more governmental intervention is required in three sub-areas; namely in (i) data sharing, (ii) self-learning algorithms and finally, (iii) marketplace(s) with walled gardens.

April 27, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Auditor Says DG COMP Should ‘scale up’ Its Enforcement—How? 

Auditor Says DG COMP Should ‘scale up’ Its Enforcement—How? 

 

The European Court of Auditors’ (‘ECA’) report The Commission’s EU merger control and antitrust proceedings: A need to scale up market oversight published in late 2020 is its first audit of DG Competition’s (‘DG COMP’) enforcement activities. It found that the ‘commission made good use of its enforcement powers’ within its ‘limited budget’, but as the report’s subtitle suggests, ‘it needed to scale up its market oversight’. It recommends more proactive enforcement, monitoring, prioritising, and ex post evaluations, better coordination with national competition authorities, and increased resources devoted to ‘own initiated’ detection.

I will show that although many of the ECA’s recommendations are welcome, its key recommendation that DG COMP increases its ‘own initiated detection activities are unsupported and may well decrease the effectiveness of DG COMP’. Here I focus on the antitrust sections of the report.

April 27, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Monday, April 26, 2021

Vertical restraints under Indian Competition Law: whither law and economics 

Vertical restraints under Indian Competition Law: whither law and economics 

 
ABSTRACT
 
The correct welfare assessment of vertical agreements in competition law is a difficult craft. The more mature jurisdictions such as the EU and the US have struggled to develop the optimal framework. This article scrutinizes vertical agreements cases of the Competition Commission of India (CCI) that is now 11 years old. The objective is to assist the CCI in strengthening its legal and economic framework vis-à-vis vertical agreements in its formative stage. The scrutiny of some leading cases revealed three types of infirmities in CCI’s cases. First, there are some legal ambiguities in the interpretation of the legislation. Secondly, the economic analysis is largely incoherent and truncated. Thirdly, there is a visible overreliance on the EU jurisprudence that does not conform to the legislative scheme of the Indian Competition Act, 2002. The article draws out some lessons towards the end.

April 26, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

The Impact of Privacy Measures on Online Advertising Markets

The Impact of Privacy Measures on Online Advertising Markets

Miguel Alcobendas

Yahoo! Research

Shunto Kobayashi

California Institute of Technology

Matthew Shum

California Institute of Technology

Abstract

Privacy regulations in online markets have ramped up in recent years, as typified by government regulation, such as the California Consumer Privacy Act (CCPA) of 2020, which allowed internet users in California to “opt-out” of behavioral tracking; as well as firm-level initiatives such as the banning of third-party cookies by major internet browsers, including Apple’s Safari and (in 2022) Google’s Chrome. Using fine-grained data from Yahoo, we estimate a structural model of bidding among Demand-Side Plat- forms (DSPs) for different types of users. Using the estimates, we simulate the counterfactual effects of expanding privacy regulations, in particular banning third-party cookies by browsers. While, as expected, such a ban would reduce publisher revenue substantially, by around 30%, it also shifts business to larger DSPs. In addition, we also consider the scenario where, in the aforementioned ban, there exists an advantaged DSP which possesses proprietary first-party information on users.

April 26, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

The Humira Patent Thicket and the Noerr-Pennington Doctrine

The Humira Patent Thicket and the Noerr-Pennington Doctrine

Ryan Knox

Yale Law School

Gregory Curfman

American Medical Association

Abstract

Humira (adalimumab) is among the best-selling drugs in the United States and around the world. Even though the core patent for Humira expired in 2016, the manufacturer, AbbVie, has continued to increase the price to consumers year-after-year, so that the 2019 average yearly retail price was $84,454. Another 7.5% price increase is expected in the near future. AbbVie’s conduct to promote the rising price of Humira was recently challenged in In Re: Humira® (Adalimumab) Antitrust Litigation, No. 19-cv-1873. In March 2019, a group of indirect payers for Humira (labor unions and health and welfare funds) filed a novel lawsuit in the U.S. District Court for the Northern District of Illinois alleging antitrust activity on the part of AbbVie in violation of Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act. The antitrust challenge, which was dismissed by the District Court on the basis of the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, is predicated on AbbVie’s patent thicket that surrounds Humira and on legal settlements it has reached with six biosimilar companies to keep them out of the market until 2023. This article examines In Re Humira and provides a legal rationale for the conclusion that the District Court’s dismissal of the case should be overturned on appeal to the United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit. The case will be heard on February 25, 2021.

April 26, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Artificial Intelligence and Market Manipulations: Ex-ante Evaluation in the Regulator's Arsenal

Artificial Intelligence and Market Manipulations: Ex-ante Evaluation in the Regulator's Arsenal

 

Nathalie de Marcellis-Warin

Center for Interuniversity Research and Analysis on Organization (CIRANO)

Frédéric M. Marty

Research Group on Law, Economics and Management (UMR CNRS 7321 GREDEG) / Université Nice Sophia Antipolis; OFCE; Center for Interuniversity Research and Analysis on Organization (CIRANO)

Eva Thelisson

Thierry Warin

HEC Montreal; CIRANO

Abstract

The digital economy's development poses questions unprecedented in their magnitude in potential market manipulations and manipulations of consumer choices. Deceptive and unfair strategies in consumer law may coexist and mutually reinforce each other with infringements in the field of competition, whether it be algorithmic collusion or abuse of a dominant position. Faced with the difficulty of detecting and sanctioning these practices ex-post, questions are raised about the sanction's dissuasive effect and its capacity to prevent possibly irreversible damage. To this end, this article considers the available supervision tools for the authorities in charge of market surveillance, the consumers or the stakeholders of the companies concerned.

April 26, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Friday, April 23, 2021

Market Power Parasites: Abusing the Power of Digital Intermediaries to Harm Competition

Market Power Parasites: Abusing the Power of Digital Intermediaries to Harm Competition

 

Noga Blickstein Shchory

University of Haifa, Faculty of Law

Michal Gal

University of Haifa - Faculty of Law

Abstract

Some digital information intermediaries, such as Google and Facebook, enjoy significant and durable market power. Concerns regarding the anti-competitive effects of such power have largely focused on conduct engaged in by the infomediaries themselves, and have led to several recent, well-publicized regulatory actions in the US and elsewhere. This article adds a new dimension to these concerns: the abuse of such power by other market players, which lack market power themselves, in a way which significantly harms the competitive process and undermines the integrity of the relevant in-formation market. We call such abusers “market power parasites.”

We provide three examples of parasitic conduct in online information markets: (1) black hat search engine optimization, (2) click fraud, and (3) fraudulent ratings and reviews. In each of these examples the manipulating parasite utilizes the infomediary’s market power to potentially turn an otherwise limited fraud into a manipulation of market dynamics, with significant anti-competitive effects.

This separation between power and conduct in the case of market power parasites creates an unwarranted lacuna which is not addressed by existing laws aimed at preventing abuses of market power. Anti-trust law does not capture such parasites because it only prohibits unilateral anti-competitive conduct if such conduct is engaged in by a monopolist. At the same time, fraud torts require proof of specific reliance and are therefore limited to a particular wrong, disregarding the broader competitive concerns resulting from parasitic conduct.

To bridge this gap, we suggest a fraud-on-the-online-information-markets rule, akin to the fraud-on-the-market rule in securities law. We propose to eliminate the rigid fraud tort requirement to prove reliance, and replace it with a presumption of reliance that will apply once the plaintiff proves harm to the integrity of an online infomediary. Our proposal strengthens competitors’ cause of action, releasing them from the arguably ill-fitting need to prove specific reliance, thereby increasing enforcement against the anti-competitive acts of market power parasites which harm the integrity of information in digital markets.

April 23, 2021 | Permalink | Comments (0)