Tuesday, October 27, 2009
China’s Antimonopoly Law—One Year Down: Part 2. China’s new merger review regime
Posted by Wentong Zheng
In my previous post on China’s Antimonopoly Law
(“AML”) (see here), I
provided a brief overview of the AML and the new developments that happened
since the AML went into effect last year.
Today I will focus on China’s new merger review regime under the AML.
Prior to the AML, an antitrust review process
was in place for foreign acquisitions of Chinese companies. No comparable process existed for mergers and
acquisitions among domestic companies.
The framework for a new merger review regime is laid out in Chapter 4 of
the AML. By not limiting its reach to
foreign acquisitions, as the previous regulation governing merger reviews did,
Chapter 4 of the AML brings within its purview mergers and acquisitions among domestic
companies.
More importantly, Chapter 4 of the AML
specifies a list of the substantive factors that will be considered in merger
reviews: (1) the market share of the undertakings (meaning business operators
or parties) involved in the relevant market and their ability to control the market;
(2) the degree of market concentration in the relevant market; (3) the effect
of the concentration on market entry and technological progress; (4) the effect
of the concentration on consumers and other undertakings; (5) the effect of the
concentration on national economic development; and (6) other factors affecting
market competition as determined by the antimonopoly enforcement agency. In the meantime, Chapter 4 of the AML
provides that a merger that otherwise would be prohibited may be allowed if it
has competitive effects that outweigh its anticompetitive effects. In addition, a merger that otherwise would be
prohibited may also be allowed if it is “in the social or public interest.”
Chapter 4 of the AML, however, only provides a
sketch of the mechanics of the new merger regime. The details of the merger review regime are
expected to be fleshed out in subsequent regulations. In March 2008, China’s State Council released
a draft merger notification and review regulation for public comments, to which
the ABA’s Antitrust Section and International Law Section responded with
extensive comments (see here—you
will need to scroll down to the middle of the document to see the comments in
English). The regulation that was
eventually promulgated in August 2008, however, was a stripped-down version
containing only notification threshold provisions. Separately, in May 2009, the Antimonopoly
Commission (the inter-agency body charged with antitrust policymaking under the
AML) issued guidelines on market definition under the AML, after soliciting
public comments (see ABA comments here). Four other regulations pertaining to the
other aspects of the merger review regime (including merger notification
procedures, merger review procedures, investigation of mergers not notified as
required by law, and investigation of mergers not reaching the notification
thresholds) are currently going through the rulemaking process.
What emerges from this hodgepodge of
regulations or proposed regulations is a merger review regime that in some
respects resembles those of Western countries and in some other respects does
not. On one hand, China’s new merger
review regime follows many of the common Western practices, such as the
adoption of the SSNIP test for market definition and the utilization of
notification thresholds based on the size of the parties to the
transactions. On the other hand, the
factors considered in merger reviews in China are apparently broader and less
predictable than those considered in Western countries. The factors considered in China are broader
because the merger authority can consider factors other than the effects of the
merger on competition, including the effects of the merger on “other
undertakings” (does it imply that China may want to protect the competitors,
not the competition?) and the effects of the merger on “national economic
development” (does that give industrial policies a role in merger
reviews?). The factors considered in
China are less predictable because the merger authority can consider any factor
that it may determine affects market competition, and factors as amorphous as
“social or public interest.”
As is true perhaps with every merger review
regime, what is more important than the texts of the merger review laws and
regulations is how merger reviews are actually conducted. The Antimonopoly Bureau of MOFCOM has assumed
responsibility for merger reviews under the AML. As of now, MOFCOM has blocked one transaction
(Coca-Cola/Huiyuan), and approved four transactions with conditions (InBev/Anheuser
Busch, Mitsubishi Rayon/Lucite, Pfizer/Wyeth and GM/Delphi).
The five merger cases that MOFCOM has blocked or
approved with conditions involve different types of merger: horizontal merger
(InBev/AB, Mitsubishi Rayon/Lucite, and Pfizer/Wyeth), vertical merger
(GM/Delphi), and conglomerate merger (Coca-Cola/Huiyuan). Unfortunately, the published decisions for
those cases tend to be very cursory. And
the decisions generally are focused more on remedies than on the evidence that
would support a conclusion of competitive harms. For two analyses of MOFCOM’s decisions in
InBev/AB, Mitsubishi Rayon/Lucite, and Coco-Cola/Huiyuan, see here and here. One thing that is clear from those cases is
that MOFCOM has demonstrated its readiness to impose both structural remedies
(such as the divestitures ordered in Mitsubishi Rayon/Lucite and Pfizer/Wyeth)
and behavioral remedies (such as the restrictions on the acquisition of
additional equity stakes in Chinese beer companies imposed in InBev/AB). But in terms of how MOFCOM would evaluate
available evidence to draw inferences about competitive harms, I don’t believe
that MOFCOM has arrived at—much less revealed—a pattern of thinking in the
decisions it has published so far.
Well, some believe that there is a pattern—a
pattern of using the merger review process as a protectionist tool against
foreign investors. This argument is
bolstered by MOFCOM’s decision to block the Coca-Cola/Huiyuan deal. You may also have noticed that all of the
transactions blocked or conditionally approved by MOFCOM involve foreign
investors. That surely smacks of
protectionism—or does it? I will offer
my takes on these issues in my next post.
October 27, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
The Slippery Slope of Addressing Collective Dominance Under Article 82 EC
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Lia Vitzilaiou (Lambadarios Law Offices) & Constantinos Lambadarios (Lambadarios Law Offices) explain The Slippery Slope of Addressing Collective Dominance Under Article 82 EC.
ABSTRACT: Article 82 EC Treaty is the instrument used by European and National Competition Authorities to address the issue of dominance in the market and its abuses by undertakings holding such positions. While this Article was primarily intended to address the issue of “single dominance,” the wording “abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position” allowed the interpretation that “collective dominance” (“CD”) may also be addressed by Article 82.
This approach may appear very effective from a theoretical point of view, but its application in the real world has proven so complex as to render it inoperative or even perilous.
October 27, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Monday, October 26, 2009
AALS Entry Level Law Faculty Hiring
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
For those on the entry level academic law job market, I have some thoughts on the Faculty Lounge Blog on how to tell which schools seem to be puffing (at best) about their interdisciplinary commitment.
October 26, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Bundling and Competition for Slots: Sequential Pricing
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Doh-Shin Jeony (Toulouse School of Economics, Universitat Pompeu Fabra) and Domenico Menicucci (Università degli Studi di Firenze) write on Bundling and Competition for Slots: Sequential Pricing.
ABSTRACT: In this paper we study, as in Jeon-Menicucci (2009), competition between sellers when each of them sells a portfolio of distinct products to a buyer having limited slots. This paper considers sequential pricing and complements our main paper (Jeon- Menicucci, 2009) that considers simultaneous pricing. First, Jeon-Menicucci (2009) find that under simultaneous individual pricing, equilibrium often does not exist and hence the outcome is often inefficient. By contrast, equilibrium always exists under sequential individual pricing and we characterize it in this paper. We find that each seller faces a trade-off between the number of slots he occupies and surplus extraction per product, and there is no particular reason that this leads to an efficient allocation of slots. Second, Jeon Menicucci (2009) find that when bundling is allowed, there always exists an efficient equilibrium but inefficient equilibria can also exist due to pure bundling (for physical products) or slotting contracts. Under sequential pricing, we find that all equilibria are efficient regardless of whether firms can use slotting contracts, and both for digital goods and for physical goods. Therefore, sequential pricing presents an even stronger case for laissez-faire in the matter of bundling than simultaneous pricing.
October 26, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Free Entry Bertrand Competition
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Prabal Roy Chowdhury (Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi Center) explains Free Entry Bertrand Competition.
ABSTRACT: This paper examines Bertrand competition under free entry, when firm size vis-a-vis market size is exogenously given. A free entry Bertrand Nash equilibrium (FEBE) exists if and only if relative market size is sufficiently large. Further, there is a unique coalition-proof Nash equilibrium price that corresponds to the minimum FEBE price, leads to average cost pricing for all active firms and is decreasing in market size.
October 26, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Preemption, Predation, and Minimum Quality Standards
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Mina Baliamoune (University of North Florida - Econ) and Stefan Lutz (U. Manchester - Econ) write on Preemption, Predation, and Minimum Quality Standards.
ABSTRACT: We present a model of vertical product differentiation and exit where a domestic and a foreign firm face fixed setup costs and quality-dependent costs of production and compete in quality and price in the domestic market. Quality-dependent costs are quadratic in qualities, but independent of the quantities produced. The domestic government may impose a minimum quality standard binding for both foreign and domestic firms. In the presence of an initial cost advantage of the domestic firm, a sufficiently high minimum quality standard set by the domestic government will enable the domestic firm to induce exit of the foreign firm, i.e. to engage in predation. However, the same standard would lead to predation by the foreign firm, if the foreign firm had the initial cost advantage.
October 26, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Charting the Future Course of International Technical Assistance
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
The DOJ/FTC Final Report on Charting the Future Course of International Technical Assistance, which is based on the February 6, 2008 Workshop is out. As some of you may know, I participated as panelist. See my comments here.
For my written work on antitrust technical assistance see here and here.
October 26, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Collective Dominance Through Tacit Coordination: The Case for Non-Coordination Between Article 82 and Merger Control "Collective Dominance" Concept
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Sophia Stephanou (OFT) describes Collective Dominance Through Tacit Coordination: The Case for Non-Coordination Between Article 82 and Merger Control "Collective Dominance" Concept.
ABSTRACT: Intervention in oligopolistic markets or—to be more precise—oligopolistic markets in which firms appear to be coordinating their actions, is a multifaceted topic; aspects of which have sparked some of the most intense debates in competition policy.
The oligopoly problem, as it is often termed, refers to firms acting in a parallel manner in the market in such a way that competition between these firms is dampened with the ultimate effect of the consumer being harmed. Oligopolies may be targeted by EC competition laws through the application of Article 81 (where behavior is explicitly coordinated), Article 82 (where behavior is explicitly or implicitly coordinated) or, prospectively, through the application of merger control rules to concentrations which are likely to enable or further facilitate coordination in a given market. The analytical issues surrounding competition law intervention in oligopolistic markets entail theoretical and practical difficulties; it is notable that the Commission's new guidance on Article 82 has explicitly excluded collective dominance from the ambit of its application.
This article will briefly outline the application of EC competition law to oligopolistic markets, with particular focus on tacit collusion between firms, the relationship between Article 82 and merger control in this respect, and the judicial pronouncement in Airtours of the conditions under which tacit coordination exists. The recent European Court of Justice (“ECJ’) Impala judgment will be examined; in particular, as regards the implications for the standard of proof in collective dominance cases and whether a different approach to collective dominance is required for merger control and Article 82 following the decision. In addition, the application of the Airtours criteria to collective dominance under Article 82 where exclusionary abuses are concerned will be discussed.
October 26, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Saturday, October 24, 2009
Most Downloaded Antitrust Law Papers - August 25, 2009 to October 24, 2009
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
October 24, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
GCR's 2009 Competition Law Review – Recent developments in competition law and policy
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
GCR's 2009 Competition Law Review
–
Recent developments in competition law and policy
Monday 16 and
Tuesday 17 November 2009,
The Conrad Hotel, Brussels
A
unique opportunity to hear some of the most influential speakers debate and
analyse the key developments in competition law. The programme will focus on
developments in four major areas: cartel enforcement, merger control,
enforcement of Article 82 and damages actions for the breach of EC antitrust
rules. Download
the conference brochure here Chairmen and speakers
include:
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
October 24, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Friday, October 23, 2009
Competition and Cooperation between Professional Sports Franchises: The Impact on Ticket Prices
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Greg Pelnar (Compass Lexecon) explains Competition and Cooperation between Professional Sports Franchises: The Impact on Ticket Prices.
ABSTRACT: An important issue in many antitrust lawsuits involving professional sports leagues and their member teams is the extent to which franchises within the same, and across different, professional sports leagues compete with one another for fans and advertisers. Complicating the issue is the fact that some sports franchises also cooperate with other franchises in the same or different leagues by, for example, participating in a joint venture to build and operate the stadium in which they will play their games or a regional sports network joint venture to televise their games. An extreme form of cooperation is common ownership: some franchises in different sports leagues have common ownership. This study investigates the impact of competition and cooperation among the franchises of the four major professional sports leagues (i.e., the National Football League, National Basketball Association, National Hockey League, and Major! League Baseball) on ticket prices for the 2008 season. The regression results suggest that the existence of one or more rival sports franchises in the same metropolitan area does not have a statistically significant impact on ticket prices. On the other hand, there is at best weak evidence that cooperation between sports franchises impacts ticket prices. These findings are consistent with a number of alternative hypotheses.
October 23, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (1) | TrackBack (0)
Collective Dominance to Coordinated Effects in EU Competition Policy
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Juan Briones (e-Konomica) discusses Collective Dominance to Coordinated Effects in EU Competition Policy.
ABSTRACT: Since the Commission first tackled the oligopoly issue under the Merger Regulation, there has been considerable development of the Commission's policy in this area and, also, very significant clarifications from the Court of Justice and the Court of First Instance. To begin with, the Commission published guidelines for its assessment of coordinated effects under the merger regulation.
Quite naturally, the oligopoly issue has arisen often, not to say systematically, since nowadays most markets do present an oligopolistic structure of supply. This is even more valid if we consider the relatively narrow relevant antitrust markets, which are typically defined by reference to substitution in demand. More often than not, leading groups of less than four suppliers account for a large combined share of output in almost any antitrust market. However, is an oligopoly in a collective dominant position? The decision in the Airtours/ First Choice case vastly extended the boundaries of the situations under which the Commission found this may be the case.
October 23, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
GCR 2010 European Antitrust Review
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
The Global Competition Review has published the comprehensive 2010 European Antitrust Review.
- Introduction
- EU Substantive Areas
- Cartels
Julian Joshua, Elvira Aliende Rodríguez - Howrey LLP - Commercial Agreements
Jochen P Beck, Tom S Pick - Hammonds LLP - Compliance
Kiran Desai - Mayer Brown - Mergers
Kyriakos Fountoukakos, Craig Pouncey - Herbert Smith LLP - Merger Efficiencies and Remedies
Alexandros Papanikolaou, Michael Rosenthal - Hunton & Williams LLP - Monopolies and Market Dominance
Alexander Böhlke - Kemmler Rapp Böhlke - Plaintiff Recovery Actions
Michael Hausfeld, Vincent Smith - Hausfeld & Co LLP - Private Antitrust Litigation
Jesús Alfaro, Tim Reher - CMS Albiñana & Suárez de Lezo and CMS Hasche Sigle - Public Affairs
Louise Harvey, Gwendoline Motte - FD Blueprint - State Aid
Paris Anestis, Sarah Jordan - Howrey LLP - Trade
Konstantinos Adamantopoulos, Riccardo Croce, Yves Melin - Hammonds LLP - Vertical Agreements
Astrid Ablasser-Neuhuber, René Plank - bpv Hügel Rechtsanwälte
- Cartels
- EU Industry Sectors
- Air Transport
Konstantinos Adamantopoulos, Riccardo Croce, Guillaume Taillandier - Hammonds LLP - Chemicals
Flavia Distefano - McKenna Long & Aldridge LLP - Energy
Riccardo Celli, Philippe Noguès, Christian Riis-Madsen - O'Melveny & Myers LLP - Pharmaceuticals
Bill Batchelor, Fiona Carlin - Baker & McKenzie - Private Equity
Pierre-André Dubois, Arabella Hinton - Kirkland & Ellis International LLP - Sport
Riccardo Croce, Stephen Sampson, Will Sparks - Hammonds LLP - Technology
Pierre-André Dubois, Arabella Hinton - Kirkland & Ellis International LLP
- Air Transport
- Country Chapters
- Austria
Astrid Ablasser-Neuhuber, Florian Neumayr - bpv Hügel Rechtsanwälte - Czech Republic
Dagmar Bicková, Arthur Braun - bpv Braun Haškovcová - Denmark
Jesper Fabricius, Asser Rung-Hansen - ACCURA - France: Abuse of Dominance
Louis Vogel, Joseph Vogel - Vogel & Vogel - France: Cartels
Natasha G Assadi-Tardif, Marc Lévy - SJ Berwin LLP - France: Merger Control
Antoine Choffel, Yann Utzschneider - Gide Loyrette Nouel AARPI - Germany: Abuse of Dominance
Michael Dietrich, Marco Hartmann-Rüppel - Taylor Wessing - Germany: Cartels
Alexander Rinne, Tilman Siebert - SJ Berwin LLP - Germany: Merger Control
Martina Maier, Philipp Werner - Howrey LLP - Germany: Private Antitrust Litigation
Tatjana Mühlbach, Alexander Rinne - SJ Berwin LLP - Greece
Despina D Samara - Calavros & Partners - Hungary
Geoff Bennett, László Kelemen, Gergely Prinz - Szabó Kelemen & Partners Attorneys - Ireland
Helen Kelly - Matheson Ormsby Prentice - Israel
Tamar Dolev-Green, Eytan Epstein, Michelle Morrison - Epstein, Chomsky, Osnat & Co - Italy: Overview
Silvia D'Alberti, Lucio D'Amario - Allen & Overy - Studio Legale Associato - Italy: Cartels
Davide Balboni, Laura Matilde Cerri - SJ Berwin LLP - Italy: Merger Control
Giorgio Alù, Giovanni M Pallone - Tonucci & Partners in alliance with Mayer Brown LLP - Italy: Telecoms
Eutimio Monaco, Domenico Siciliano - Bird & Bird - Latvia
Martins Gailis, Liga Hartmane - Kļaviņś & Slaidiņś LAWIN - Netherlands: Cartels
Esther Glerum-van Aalst, Marleen de Putter, Andre Reznitchenko - Kneppelhout & Korthals - Netherlands: Merger Control
Michel Chatelin, Simone Schippers - Eversheds Faasen - Portugal
Mário Marques Mendes, Pedro Vilarinho Pires - Marques Mendes & Associados - Romania
Mihaela Ion, Silviu Stoica - Popovici Nitu & Asociatii - Russia
Natalia Ivolgina, Tapani Manninen - Hannes Snellman Attorneys Ltd - Spain: Overview
Juan Jiménez Laiglesia, Jorge Masía, Arantzazu Ruiz-Villanueva, Luis Sotelo - DLA Piper Spain - Spain: Cartels
Ramón García-Gallardo - SJ Berwin LLP - Spain: Merger Control
Marcos Araujo, Konstantin J Jörgens, Crisanto Pérez-Abad - Garrigues - Spain: Telecoms and Media
Blanca Escribano, Sofía Fontanals, Mar Quirós - Bird & Bird - Switzerland
Andreas Burger, Marcel Dietrich, Franz Hoffet - Homburger - Turkey
Metin Somay - Somay Hukuk Burosu in collaboration with Hammonds LLP - Ukraine
Irina Drofenko, Irina Nazarova - Engarde Attorneys-at-law in collaboration with Hammonds LLP - United Kingdom: Overview
Julia Joseph, Becket McGrath - Berwin Leighton Paisner LLP - United Kingdom: Cartels
Amanda Butler, Philipp Girardet, Simon Holmes - SJ Berwin LLP - United Kingdom: Private Enforcement
Neil Davis, Lesley Farrell - SJ Berwin LLP
- Austria
October 23, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Thursday, October 22, 2009
Repealing Insurers’ Antitrust Exemption Under McCarran-Ferguson: Less There Than Meets the Eye?
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Tim Greaney (St. Louis Law) has a posted a discussion on Repealing Insurers’ Antitrust Exemption Under McCarran-Ferguson: Less There Than Meets the Eye?
October 22, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Bundling and Competition for Slots: On the Portfolio Effects of Bundling
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Doh-Shin Jeony (Toulouse School of Economics, Universitat Pompeu Fabra) and Domenico Menicucci (Università degli Studi di Firenze) explain Bundling and Competition for Slots: On the Portfolio Effects of Bundling.
ABSTRACT: We consider competition among sellers when each of them sells a portfolio of distinct products to a buyer having limited slots. We study how bundling affects competition for slots. Under independent pricing, equilibrium often does not exist and hence the outcome is often inefficient. When bundling is allowed, each seller has an incentive to bundle his products and an efficient equilibrium always exists. Furthermore, in the case of digital goods, all equilibria are efficient if slotting contracts are prohibited. We also identify portfolio e¤ects of bundling and analyze the consequences on horizontal mergers. Finally, we derive clear-cut policy implications.
October 22, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
The Doctrine of Collective Dominance: All Together Forever?
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Frederic Depoortere (Skadden) & Giorgio Motta (Skadden) ask The Doctrine of Collective Dominance: All Together Forever?
ABSTRACT: What are the policy objectives underlying the collective dominance (“CD”) doctrine under Article 82 of the EC Treaty and what is the legal test governing its application? Even today these questions remain partially unanswered. EC competition law still appears to lack a robust and consistent legal standard for identifying when companies should be held “collectively dominant” and when their conduct constitutes an abuse. In addition, the lack of clear policy objectives has not assisted the debate on these issues. They may even have lead to a significant decrease in the European Commission’s interest in CD situations: the recent Guidance on Enforcement Priorities (“Enforcement Guidance”), which presumably sets out the Commission’s enforcement priorities under Article 82, does not cover collective dominance at all.
Possible policy objectives for CD are outside the scope of this article, which concentrates on providing some observations on the test currently endorsed by the Community Courts (“Courts”) to identify abuses of CD. In its Compagnie Maritime Belge judgment (“CMB”), as confirmed by subsequent case law, the ECJ proposes a three-prong test: (i) the existence of a collective position/entity, (ii) such collective position being dominant, and (iii) the abuse by the collectively dominant entity. The first and third prongs are the main focus of this article.
October 22, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Competition and Antitrust Policy in the Enlarged European Union - A Level Playing Field?
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Jens Hölscher, University of Brighton and Johannes Florian Stephan, Technical University Freiberg address Competition and Antitrust Policy in the Enlarged European Union - A Level Playing Field?
ABSTRACT: With the central and east European countries (CEECs) increasingly included into the international division of labour in the European economic space, we are prompted to ask whether this integration operates on a level playing field with respect to competition policy. In fact, our analysis reveals that effectiveness of implementation of competition law and policy and intensity of competition are lower in the CEECs. We find no reason to believe that the new eastern EU members struggle with the recent reforms of competition policy in the EU, nor do we see the necessity for policy action to spur effective implementation.
October 22, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
From Formalism to Effects? – The Commission’s Communication on Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 EC
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Nicolas Petit (University of Liege - Law) addresses From Formalism to Effects? – The Commission’s Communication on Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 EC.
ABSTRACT: The purpose of the present article is to offer thoughts on the “Guidance Communication on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty” and, in particular, to review the requirements which the Commission must meet in Article 82 EC cases when it purports to apply the Communication’s economics-oriented, effects-based. In addition, this article seeks to assess whether the Communication’s effects-based approach really entails a paradigmatic shift towards increased competition economics, comparable to the (r)evolution that has taken place in other areas of EC antitrust enforcement since the early 2000. It comes to the conclusion that whilst the Communication marks a welcome economic sophistication of the Commission’s Article 82 EC enforcement policy, it nonetheless often fails to go beneath the surface of modern antitrust economics, and thus provide only limited guidance to firms and their counsels.
October 22, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Wednesday, October 21, 2009
It's the Market Power, Stupid! Stock Return Patterns in International Bank M&A
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Yassin Hankir, Frankfurt School of Finance & Management - FIPEMA, Christian Rauch, E-Finance Lab, and Marc P. Umber, Frankfurt School of Finance & Management, Goethe University Frankfurt - Department of Finance explain It's the Market Power, Stupid! Stock Return Patterns in International Bank M&A.
ABSTRACT: This paper analyzes capital market reactions to international bank M&A. We investigate combined stock return patterns of targets, bidders, and their peers upon takeover announcement, and closing or withdrawal. We distinguish five common M&A hypotheses and relate characteristic and mutually exclusive abnormal stock return patterns to each hypothesis. We find that investors believe in gains through the exploitation of market power by the post-merger entity. In a multinomial logistic model we show that patterns related to market power significantly concur with large relative target size, intra-industry mergers, and increasing market concentration, suggesting a substantial lessening of competition through M&A.
October 21, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Competition Among the Big and the Small
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Ken-Ichi Shimomura, Kobe University and Jacques-François Thisse, Catholic University of Louvain - Center for Operations Research and Econometrics explain Competition Among the Big and the Small.
ABSTRACT: Armchair evidence shows that many industries are made of a few big commercial or manufacturing firms, which are able to affect the market outcome, and of a myriad of small family-run businesses with very few employees, each of which has a negligible impact on the market. Examples can be found in apparel, catering, publishers and bookstores, retailing, finance and insurances, and IT industries. We provide a new general equilibrium framework that encapsulates both market structures. Due to the higher toughness of the market, the entry of big firms leads them to sell more through a market expansion effect, which is generated by the exit of small firms. Furthermore, the level of social welfare increases with the number of oligopolistic firms because the procompetitive effect associated with the entry of a big firm dominates the resulting decrease in product variety.
October 21, 2009 | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)