Tuesday, July 22, 2008
Facilitating Practices and Concerted Action Under Section 1 of the Sherman Act
Posted by D. Daniel Sokol
Bill Page of the University of Florida Levin College of Law recently posted Facilitating Practices and Concerted Action Under Section 1 of the Sherman Act.
ABSTRACT: Successful collusion requires that
rivals reach consensus on the key terms and deploy some means of
detecting and penalizing cheaters, usually by tracking rivals'
transaction prices. Economists have shown that firms in an oligopoly
can, in certain conditions, achieve noncompetitive prices and outputs
without an express agreement by making choices that anticipate each
others' likely responses. "Facilitating practices" are mechanisms that
enhance rival firms' ability to police such an arrangement. If firms
expressly agree to adopt one of these facilitating practices, for
example as a trade association rule, and the effect of the practice is
to reduce competition, then that agreement may be independently illegal
under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Moreover, the Sherman Act may
preempt a state law that requires rivals to use a facilitating
practice. A more difficult question arises, however, where the firms
each adopt the same facilitating practice without any express
agreement: does parallel pricing together with parallel adoption of
facilitating practices allow a court to infer the requisite agreement?
Both Donald Turner and Richard Posner believed that, unlike simple
parallel pricing, the parallel adoption of a facilitating practice that
permits noncompetitive pricing should be unlawful, because the problem
of remedy is mitigated.
But
conduct is not evidence of an anticompetitive agreement simply because
it can be enjoined. Facilitating practices may do more than simply
facilitate rivals' efforts to achieve an inefficient oligopoly price.
They also may provide certain immediate benefits to consumers by, among
other things, reducing search or transaction costs. In these
circumstances, the firms' adoption of the practice might well be for
the benign reason rather than the collusive reason. Courts will not
easily infer an agreement from the parallel adoption of facilitating
practices where the practices have beneficial functions apart from
facilitating price coordination.
Unfortunately, the stated
legal definitions of agreement under which courts evaluate
circumstantial evidence, including facilitating practices, are
inadequate. In this article, I review the deficiencies of the present
law governing the definition and proof of agreement under Section 1 and
propose that the law should recognize that communication among rivals
is necessary for concerted action. I then examine cases involving
facilitating practices in a variety of Section 1 contexts, and suggest
that the courts have come to recognize the importance of communications
among rivals in evaluating whether the evidence warrants an inference
of agreement.
https://lawprofessors.typepad.com/antitrustprof_blog/2008/07/facilitating-pr.html