PropertyProf Blog

Editor: Stephen Clowney
Univ. of Kentucky College of Law

A Member of the Law Professor Blogs Network

Friday, March 14, 2008

Sex Beds and Virtual Land: What can Virtual Property Do for Property?

Thanks for the introduction, Ben! Ben's description of me as someone "who also teaches Property" is just right; I started teaching Property after over ten years of teaching upper-level Property-related courses such as Secured Transactions, Bankruptcy, and Electronic Commerce. My years teaching Secured Transactions piqued my interest in intangible assets, which is what brings me to sex beds and virtual land. Sex beds and virtual land were at the center of two controversies involving the property rights of participants in the wildly popular virtual world, Second Life. In later posts, I'll explain how property rights arise in Second Life, but in this post, I would like to introduce the two disputes, Eros v. Simon and Bragg v. Linden Research.

In Eros, several Second Life merchants sued Thomas Simon, who had been making and selling unauthorized copies of the plaintiffs’ products. The plaintiffs are described in the complaint as some of the most successful merchants in Second Life. Kevin Alderman, the principal of the lead plaintiff, Eros, built the first in-world sex bed and sells a host of adult-themed items, and the other plaintiffs sell items such as virtual clothing, virtual furniture and avatar skins. According to the complaint, the items sold by the plaintiffs are protected by trademark and copyright laws. The defendant copied all of these items and started selling them to Second Life residents himself. All of the objects were marked “no copy” or “no transfer.” These markings make copying theoretically impossible, but there are security flaws in Second Life that enable copying of such objects. The plaintiffs sued for, among other things, copyright and trademark infringement.   

The plaintiff in Bragg wanted to develop "real estate" in Second Life. To do so, he joined Second Life and started to acquire virtual land. A member purchases virtual land with the Second Life currency, Lindens. Lindens can be freely traded, and the Second Life web site includes a currency exchange, the Lindex. Today, $1 equals 265 Lindens. So, Mr. Bragg bought Lindens, and then bought land.

There are several ways to buy land in Second Life, one of which is by auction. Bragg bought numerous pieces of land and then discovered an exploit in the system that allowed him to buy land cheaply. His use of the exploit violated the Second Life Terms of Service, so Linden (the operator of Second Life) terminated his accounts, denying him access to his land and Lindens. Bragg sued Linden, alleging that Linden converted his property.

Both of these matters settled, but they provide property scholars with the opportunity to analyze rights in intangible assets in the context of intangible assets that look and act an awful lot like real property and tangible personal property. More on that next week.

Juliet Moringiello

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]


March 14, 2008 in Intellectual Property | Permalink | Comments (3) | TrackBack (0)

Monday, March 3, 2008

Weiser and Hatfield on Property in Spectrum

Phil Weiser and Dale N. Hatfield (Univ. of Colorado) have posted Spectrum Policy Reform and the Next Frontier of Property Rights on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

The scarcity of wireless spectrum reflects a costly failure of regulation. In practice, large swaths of spectrum are vastly underused or used for low value activities, but the regulatory system prevents innovative users from gaining access to such spectrum through marketplace transactions. In calling for the propertyzing of swaths of spectrum as a replacement for the current command-and-control system, many scholars have wrongfully assumed the simplicity of how such a regime would work in practice. In short, many scholars suggest that spectrum property rights can easily borrow key principles from trespass law, reasoning that since property rights work well for land, they can work well for spectrum rights as well. But as we explain, spectrum is not the same as land, and a poorly designed property rights regime for spectrum might even be worse than the legacy model of spectrum regulation.

This Article addresses three central questions that confront the design and implementation of property rights in spectrum. First, it suggests how policymakers must develop a set of rights and remedies around spectrum property rights that reflect the fact that radio signals defy boundaries and can propagate in unpredictable ways. In particular, if policymakers simply created rights in spectrum and enforced them like rights in land (i.e., with injunctions for trespass), they would invite strategic behavior: spectrum speculators would buy licenses for the sole purpose of suing other licensees when their transmission systems created interference outside the permissible boundary (i.e., act as spectrum trolls). Second, it rejects the suggestion that policymakers establish a unitary property right for spectrum, arguing that policymakers should zone the spectrum by establishing different levels of protection against interference (i.e., an ability to transmit signals with more latitude) in different frequency bands. Finally, this Article discusses what institutional strategy will best facilitate the development of the property right and its enforcement, concluding that an administrative agency - be it a new one or a reformed FCC - is better positioned than a court to develop and enforce the rules governing the use of spectrum so as to facilitate technological progress and prevent parties with antiquated equipment from objecting to more efficient uses of spectrum.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

March 3, 2008 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, December 21, 2007

Moringiello on Estates in Virtual Property

Juliet Moringeillo (Widener University School of Law) has posted Towards a System of Estates in Virtual Property on SSRN.

Virtual worlds such as Second Life have received a lot of press in the United States recently. As individuals and businesses participate in these virtual worlds, questions arise regarding the application of existing laws to their virtual world transactions. Many questions have arisen regarding the property rights of participants in virtual worlds, and a Second Life member recently sued Linden Research, the company that developed Second Life, alleging that Second Life converted his virtual property. The questions regarding the legal nature of virtual world assets tend to mirror the questions regarding intangible rights generally, as courts have tended to struggle over whether these rights are property rights or contract rights. In this paper, I propose that the principle of numerus clausus be applied to virtual property, so that courts faced with disputes over such assets will have mandatory property forms to which to resort. Such an approach would limit the ability of vendors of such rights to customize them through their contracts, which are commonly embodied in electronically-presented standard forms.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delays in posting]

December 21, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship, Virtual Property | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, November 16, 2007

Van Houweling on The New Servitudes

Molly Shaffer van Houweling (UC Berkeley - Boalt) has posted The New Servitudes on SSRN. Here's the abstract:

In the age of electronic commerce, consumers routinely acquire intangible products without engaging in any direct human interaction. These products—computer programs, digital music, etc.—often arrive bearing terms that purport to limit the sticks in the consumers' bundles of rights in ways that depart from the background limitations imposed by intellectual property law. For example, a consumer who has downloaded a computer program from the Internet might be presented with a screen of text imposing myriad restrictions on how the program may be used; installation commences only when the consumer clicks “I agree.” Courts in the United States have increasingly enforced such restrictions—labeling them “click-wrap licenses” and applying to them the same contractual concepts that govern face-to-face exchanges of promises. Similar licensing approaches—albeit with quite different substantive terms—have been extended into the realms of “free software” and “free culture.”

The law of tangible property offers a different lens through which to view these contemporary techniques for distributing and controlling intangible products. When someone buys land that is purportedly subject to use restrictions imposed by a prior owner, those restrictions are sometimes enforced as “servitudes”—non-possessory property interests that attach to land and impose their restrictions and obligations on generation after generation of landowners. Like click-wrap licenses and similar techniques of the digital age, use restrictions imposed by servitudes bind remote purchasers with whom the beneficiaries of the restrictions may have no direct relationship. They do not arise from any human communication, but instead “run with” the burdened assets and automatically bind current possessors.

Although servitudes are a familiar feature of contemporary real property law, they have long encountered judicial skepticism that has generated a host of doctrinal complications. This skepticism has been even more pronounced in the context of servitudes applied to items of tangible personal property. But it finds little expression in the current contractual approach to interpreting licenses attached to intangible products.

In this article I develop a comprehensive account of the evolving jurisprudence of servitudes as applied to both land and personal property, identifying the sources of traditional servitude skepticism in order better to evaluate the new generation of running restrictions on intangible informational goods. I apply the lessons I draw from the old servitudes to paradigmatic examples of contemporary licensing practices—including Microsoft end-user license agreements, the Free Software Foundation's General Public License, and Creative Commons licenses. The lessons I draw from the old servitudes bring the problems—and also the promise—of these new servitudes into sharp focus, providing a new framework within which to analyze emerging electronic commerce practices while contributing doctrinally- and historically-grounded insights into the ongoing debate about the proper relationship between intellectual property and the public domain.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

November 16, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Land Use, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Wednesday, October 10, 2007

Marilyn Monroe's Legacy

For a woman who died 45 years ago, Marilyn Monroe has been in the news a lot lately.  On the one hand, a dispute is raging in California and New York over who has the rights to images of Marilyn, reported in this story (hat tip:  Wills, Trusts, and Estates Prof Blog).  The California legislature recently passed a bill that would make a celebrity's right of publicity bequeathable by will even if the celebrity died before rights of publicity were recognized by the courts in California.  The bill awaits the signature of California's governor, Arnold Schwarzenegger, who has personal experience with rights of publicity.  On the other hand, the BBC reported last week that several "lost" dresses worn by Marilyn are being exhibited in the U.K., including the famous dress Monroe wore in the publicity shot for The Seven Year Itch while standing over a New York subway grating.  So, if the California bill is signed, those who don't want to pay for the photo rights can go to Britain to see the dress instead.

Whether the right of publicity should be bequeathable is an interesting question.  On the one hand, if the reason for recognizing the right of publicity is that a celebrity's persona is an extension of her personhood, then it isn't obvious that such a right should continue to be protected after her death.  But if the right of publicity is meant to encourage people to work hard and become famous, so that they can reap the benefits of the persona they develop, then that same incentive argument might justify a power of testation over the right of publicity.  There is also an interesting constitutional issue here.  The Supreme Court held in Hodel v. Irving that a complete abrogation of the power of testation may be an unconstitutional taking.  Given that California and several other states recognize a common-law right of publicity, in addition to a statutory right, can the state take away the power to bequeath this publicity right by will without compensating the holder of the right?

The museum exhibition of Monroe's dresses raises another question.  In her will, Monroe bequeathed her "personal effects and clothing" to her acting coach, Lee Strasberg, "it being my desire that he distribute these, in his sole discretion, among my friends, colleagues and those to whom I am devoted."  In fact, however, as explained in a recent article by Alyssa DiRusso, He Says, She Asks:  Gender, Language, and the Law of Precatory Words in Wills, Strasberg never distributed any of Monroe's personal effects to anyone; in fact, he requested that some of her possessions be returned by a colleague to whom she had given them.

There is no indication that any of the dresses on exhibit in the U.K. were part of the bequest to Strasberg.  But suppose that they were.  Should Strasberg have a legal obligation to distribute them to her friends and colleagues?  DiRusso argues that women tend to use precatory language (deemed nonbinding) in wills where men would issue a binding command.  Here is the abstract of her article:

Precatory language is often insufficient to create a legally binding trust. Men and women choose different language to express themselves. What is the connection between these two statements?

This article reviews the current status of the law of precatory language, concluding that whether a will including precatory words (such as wish, ask, or recommend) will be construed to create a trust is at best a hit or miss proposition. The article continues to explore the psychology literature on differences in language ability and expression between men and women. Finally, the article ties these two disciplines together, analyzing original empirical data collected from 324 subjects and concluding that women are indeed more likely to use precatory language than men. The article concludes by noting the impact our heightened understanding of gender and precatory language has for courts, legal scholars, and practicing attorneys.

Should the court construe Monroe's words differently because she is female?  This is not an easy question, particularly when the will was drafted by an attorney rather than by the testator herself.  But DiRusso is right to call attention to the law's apparent blindness to gender differences in language.

Continue reading

October 10, 2007 in Intellectual Property | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Thursday, August 23, 2007

Boonk and Lodder on Website Access

Martine Boonk (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) and Arno R. Lodder (Free University of Amsterdam) have posted Regulating Website Access for Automated Means Such as Search Bots and Agents: Property or Contract? on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

This paper deals with legal issues concerning website access for software agents, notably the question how terms and conditions on a website can be presented in such a way that software agents and other automated programs exploring the internet can adhere to them. We discuss the technology behind requesting website content, and indicate for what reasons website owners regulate access to their web sites.

The core of the paper analyses the legal grounds for applying terms and conditions to websites: property rights and contractual duties. In our discussion we take into account the theory of browse-wrap licenses and case law from both Common Law and Civil Law countries. We also argue that under specific circumstances, the mere visiting of a website may constitute a contract.

The question as to whether what holds for human users also holds for automated means is given special attention. Finally, we introduce ways to more effectively regulate website access for automated means.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

August 23, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, August 17, 2007

Driesen on Infrastructure Commons

David M. Driesen (Syracuse) has posted An Economic Dynamic Approach to the Infrastructure Commons on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

This brief essay comments upon and extends Brett Frischman's idea of the infrastructure commons, i.e. that certain commons resources function as infrastructure. After suggesting some refinements of the infrastructure commons theory, this essay shows how an economic dynamic approach to law (see David M. Driesen, The Economic Dynamics of Environmental Law (MIT Press 2003) can help strengthen the case for proper management of the infrastructure commons, helping bolster the case for preserving the commons and identifying some of its limitations. The essay, like Professor Frischman's original article, applies infrastructure commons theory to both environmental and intellectual property resources.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

August 17, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Natural Resources, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Monday, July 23, 2007

Smith on IP as Property

Henry E. Smith (Yale Law School) has posted Intellectual Property as Property: Delineating Entitlements in Information on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

This Article proposes that intellectual property's close relationship to property stems from the role that information costs play in the delineation and enforcement of exclusion rights. As theorists have emphasized, the nonrivalness of information causes exclusive rights to be more costly in terms of forgone use than in the law of tangible property. But if intellectual property does not solve a problem of allocation to information, it can play a role in allowing those who find and develop information to appropriate the return from their rival inputs. It is on the cost side that exclusion emerges as a possible shortcut: exclusive rights in information are simple, indirect, and low-cost devices for solving the problem of appropriating the return from these rival inputs. Building on a framework that identifies exclusion and governance as complementary strategies for defining property rights, the Article derives some propositions about which factors can be expected to push toward and away from exclusion in delineating entitlements to information. The role that exclusion plays in keeping the system of entitlements over information modular - allowing information to be hidden behind metaphorical boundaries - is both its strength and its weakness. Because exclusion is both more costly and potentially more beneficial as interconnected information becomes more valuable, it is an empirical question whether we would expect more exclusion - and whether it would be desirable. The Article uses this information-cost theory to explain some of the basic differences between the more tort-like copyright regime and the more property-like patent law. The information-cost theory also has implications for suggestive sources of empirical evidence on structures of entitlements, such as rules within business organizations. Intellectual property, like property in general, can be seen as (at best) a second-best solution of a complex coordination problem of attributing outputs to inputs.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

July 23, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Thursday, July 12, 2007

Menell on IP and the Property Rights Movement

Peter S. Menell (Boalt) has posted Intellectual Property and the Property Rights Movement on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

The article examines the recent efforts of the Property Rights Movement to expand the “property tent” to emcompass intellectual property. In eBay v. MercExchange, a case addressing the standard for injunctive relief in patent cases, some property rights advocates argued that the Supreme Court should look to trespass and encroachment cases to establish a strong presumption favoring a right to a permanent injunction. More generally, Professor Richard Epstein has suggested that “structural unity” between real and intellectual property should guide courts and legislatures to use the real property mold in evolving intellectual property law. This article shows that the origins, philosophical foundations, and economic ramifications of real and intellectual property are quite distinct and that uncritically basing intellectual property law on a real property analogy is likely to cause more harm than good. The article also suggests that property rights advocates' effort to expand the “property tent” to include intellectual property is likely to backfire, calling attention to the interdependency of resources and the need for a significant government role in governing allocation and use of property.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

July 12, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Monday, June 18, 2007

NY Times on Virtual Gold Farming

Those of you interested in virtual property and the economies of MMOGs should check out an article from yesterday's NY Times Magazine on Chinese gold farms -- companies that accumulate virtual property and sell it for real-world money.  The article also mentions a class-action lawsuit filed by players of one MMOG against retailers of virtual property.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

June 18, 2007 in Intellectual Property | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, May 18, 2007

Moringiello on Tangibility

My colleague Juliet Moringiello (Widener) has posted False Categories in Commercial Law: The (Ir)Relevance of (In)Tangibility on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

Almost fifty years ago, Grant Gilmore, the co-reporter for Article 9 of the Uniform Commercial Code, recognized the difficulties that intangible assets pose for commercial law, noting that “if you can see it, count, weigh and measure it, it exists; if you can't, it doesn't.” The original drafters of Article 9 were concerned primarily about facilitating secured transactions in intangible payment rights. Today, the difficulties that Gilmore identified are multiplied by the proliferation of electronic assets, such as Internet domain names and assets in virtual worlds such as Second Life.

Although Article 9 of the UCC was revised fairly recently, one area in which it does not adequately cover electronic assets is in its enforcement provisions. The enforcement provisions in Article 9 are based on a false distinction, a distinction based on the tangibility or intangibility of the asset in question. While courts can modernize commercial law through their decisions, courts faced with emerging electronic assets tend to cling to the same false distinction, viewing tangible property as the property paradigm and viewing many intangible assets as either new forms of “intellectual property,” or worse, as “not property” at all.

This paper explores the problems caused by commercial law's fealty, in the creditors' remedies area, to the notion of tangibility, and suggests that courts and other lawmaking bodies look to general property principles in fashioning rules to govern electronic assets. The article analyzes recent judicial decisions and legislative enactments dealing with electronic assets and identifies some common mistakes that lawmaking institutions make in dealing with these new types of assets. The article concludes by analyzing some older decisions in which courts were forced to refine the concept of possession to account for new types of assets and suggests that courts dealing with electronic assets look to these, and not necessarily to other cases dealing with intangibles, in fashioning rules to govern electronic assets.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

May 18, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Monday, April 23, 2007

Bartow on Naming Rights

Ann Bartow (University of South Carolina) has posted Trademarks of Privilege: Naming Rights and the Physical Public Domain on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

This paper critiques the branding and labeling of the physical public domain with the names of corporations, commercial products, and individuals. It suggests that under-recognized public policy conflicts exist between the naming policies and practices of political subdivisions, trademark law, and right of publicity doctrines. It further argues that naming acts are often undemocratic and unfair, illegitimately appropriate public assets for private use, and constitute a limited form of compelled speech. It concludes by considering alternative mechanisms by which the names of public facilities could be chosen.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

April 23, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Thursday, April 5, 2007

Property Students in Second Life

At Terra Nova, Rachel Goda has an interesting post on sending first year property students into Second Life to see how property concepts are reflected in the virtual world.  Hat tip:  David Post at the VC.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

April 5, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Personal Property | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, March 9, 2007

Isaacs on Takings and Patents

Davida H. Isaacs (Northern Kentucky University) has posted Not All Property is Created Equal: Why Modern Courts Resist Applying the Takings Clause to Patents, and Why They are Right to Do So on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

After a century of disregard, the question of whether patents are entitled to protection under the Fifth Amendment's Takings Clause has recently become a topic of scholarly and judicial debate. While one might have expected this issue to have been settled long before, it is only the recent burgeoning of patentholders' regulatory takings claims that has made this question one of pressing interest. Thus far scholarship on the issue has focused on whether or not patents have historically been characterized as "property". Meanwhile, last year's rejection by the Federal Circuit of a patentholder's right to assert a Takings Clause claim led to both external criticism as well as a vocal dissent by an esteemed member of that court.

Considering the issue from a new angle, this article demonstrates that determination of patents' status as "property" is a relevant but incomplete analysis of the constitutional question. That is because the Supreme Court has already concluded that some "property interests," particularly federal benefits, are entitled to Due Process Clause protection but are not entitled to Takings Clause protection. Patents are similar federal entitlements, offered only because they serve society, and thus they are not entitled to the full panoply of constitutional protections. Moreover, if patentholders could assert regulatory takings claims, the fear of costly claims could very well deter the government from making worthwhile policy changes. For instance, there is currently significant public concern about the high prices of pharmaceuticals resulting from drug companies' patent privileges. Refusing to grant patentholders the right to a Takings Clause remedy will prevent society from being stuck with earlier suboptimal patent policies. In sum, permitting patents to trigger takings claims is neither compelled by modern Supreme Court precedent nor wise as a policy matter.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

March 9, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship, Takings | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Wednesday, February 28, 2007

Menell on Property Rights Movement and IP

Peter S. Menell (Boalt Hall) has posted The Property Rights Movement's Embrace of Intellectual Property: True Love Or Doomed Relationship? on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

The recent Supreme Court battle over the legal standard for permanent injunctions in patents cases (eBay v. MercExchange) marked an important new front in the Property Rights Movement's campaign to establish a strict and broad interpretation of property rights and their enforcement. This essay explores whether Professor Richard Epstein's embrace of intellectual property rights is likely to produce a durable marriage of traditional property rights theory and intellectual property protection or merely represents a fling that will not withstand divisive relational pressures. It shows that philosophical, functional, intellectual, and political tensions stand in the way of a stable or enduring relationship between advocates of strong and unyielding property rights and intellectual property owners. The need for dynamism and adaptability within the intellectual property rights field may well weaken the support for absolutism in property jurisprudence and policy, reinforcing the shift away from the Blackstonian conception of property.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

February 28, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Thursday, January 11, 2007

Safrin on How Property Begets Property

Sabrina Safrin (Rutgers - Newark) has posted Chain Reaction: How Property Begets Property on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

Classic theories for the evolution of property rights consider the emergence of private property to be a progressive development reflecting a society's movement to a more efficient property regime. This article argues that instead of this progressive dynamic, a more subtle and damaging chain reaction dynamic can come into play that traditional theories for intellectual and other property rights neither anticipate nor explain. The article suggests that the expansion of intellectual and other property rights have an internally generative dynamic. Drawing upon contemporary case studies, the article argues that property rights evolve in reaction to each other. The creation of property rights for some engenders the demand for related property rights by others. These demands and resulting recognition of property rights may have little to do with the value of the resource in question or efficiency concerns. Today's global economy makes the collateral creation of property rights more pronounced because changes in property rights in one country can trigger unanticipated changes in the property regimes of another.

The article offers three explanations for why property rights beget more property rights. The first draws on group behavior theory; the second focuses on a breach of a cooperative norm; the third flows from the right of exclusion. The chain reaction evolution of property rights helps explain why intellectual property rights have vastly expanded over the last several decades and continue to expand. It also sheds light on the increased transformation of spaces and tangible goods from open access or commons property to exclusive ownership regimes. The chain reaction theory of the evolution of intellectual and other property rights has considerable implications. It anticipates the development of unexpected, extensive and ultimately undesirable property regimes.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

January 11, 2007 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Thursday, December 7, 2006

Kieff and Paredes on the IP Anticommons

F. Scott Kieff and Troy A. Paredes (both of Washington University School of Law) have posted Engineering a Deal: Toward a Private Ordering Solution to the Anticommons Problem on SSRN.  Here's the abstract:

The problems of the intellectual property (“IP”) anticommons are infamous. Many people fear that the potential for vast numbers of IP rights to cover a single good or service will prevent an enterprise from even attempting to launch a business for fear of being unduly taxed or retarded or simply held up. This Article offers a solution based on private ordering within the context of existing laws. This approach uses a limited liability entity structured so that IP owners are given an actual stake in the operating business and thus an incentive to participate in the enterprise; and yet at the same time, the IP owners face a number of constraints that mitigate their interest in acting opportunistically by holding out. Through careful attention to IP owner payoffs and self-restraint, the proposed structure is designed to coordinate behavior among relevant IP owners, thus overcoming the anticommons problem. This approach is designed to help lawyers serve their role as transaction cost engineers who can structure relationships in ways that get deals done.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

December 7, 2006 in Intellectual Property, Property Theory, Recent Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Monday, October 30, 2006

Why YouTube Might Not Have Infringement Problems

Tim Wu (Columbia Law School) has a great post on Slate explaining why YouTube isn't likely to go the way of Napster.  This issue came up during my short tour through IP law in my Property class; if you cover this stuff, it might be worth directing your students to Wu's post.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

October 30, 2006 in Intellectual Property | Permalink | Comments (1) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, September 22, 2006

Seizing O.J.'s Right To Publicity

I've been meaning to post on this since I heard about it a few days ago, but Eugene Volokh saved me the trouble with an interesting post on Fred Goldman's attempt to seize O.J.'s right of publicity.  The case will turn in part on whether the right to publicity is viewed as property or as something kind-of-like-property-but-not-quite-property.

Ben Barros

[Comments are held for approval, so there will be some delay in posting]

September 22, 2006 in Intellectual Property | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)

Friday, August 25, 2006

Art and Property

Today's New York Times carries a review of a new exhibit of Walker Evans photographs, Walker Evans. Or is It?, that raises some interesting questions about the nature of intellectual property.  (The reviewer's focus is on the questions raised about the nature of photography; I merely extend the inquiry a bit here.)  Some of Walker's prints from the 1930s that are in the public domain were digitally scanned and printed in an enlarged format, now on display until November 17 at the UBS Art Gallery on Sixth Ave. in New York.  The result, as the reviewer tells us, are images that are "seductive and luxurious -- velvety, full of rich detail, poster-size in a few cases and generally cinematic." Because they are unlike the smaller-format silver gelatin prints that Evans made "the pictures are read differently, more piecemeal, in a way that film in a theater is viewed differently from an image on television or on a computer screen."  From an artistic standpoint, the reviewer wonders whether photography is closer to music and theater, where each performance is an interpretation of an original score or text, or painting, where there is but one object, and copies are fraudulent.  From a property perspective, what is the property that inheres in a photographic image?  The economic rights are fairly obvious.  I'm more interested in what the civil law terms the moral rights of artists. Of course, the artist can control this by retaining the copyright, and because these Evans prints are in the public domain there is no issue of whether Evans's economic property rights have been violated.  That raises the Visual Artists Rights Act of 1990, which brings into federal law a portion of the civil law notion of moral rights of artists, and provides at 17 U.S. C. 106A (a)(3)(A) that a visual artist has the right "to prevent any intentional distortion, mutilation, or other modification of that work which would be prejudicial to his or her honor or reputation . . . ."  From viewing the photos on display in today's Times, in my humble view, the digitial prints surely don't violate this statute.  But what of the larger, more philosophical, point?  What does a photographer own?  Is a photographic image more like a painting or a musical score? 

Calvin Massey

Comments are held for approval, so there may be a delay in posting

      

August 25, 2006 in Intellectual Property | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)