Friday, May 8, 2009

The Invisible Hand Meets the Internal Point of View: The Strange Mish-Mash of Law & Economics

Posted by Jeff Lipshaw

Richard Posner published an eminently sensible analysis of the bursting of the credit bubble in the Wall Street Journal the other day (a prelude, I assume, to his new book, The Failure of Capitalism, which he no doubt wrote in a couple nights of intense work).  I'm not sure what's going on in his thinking, but the virtue Images-2 of having what appears to be very few unpublished thoughts is that we ankle-biters have all sorts of grist for the mill when we find changes in thinking or contradictions.  For some reason, it got me thinking about some of the, well, (how should I say this?) odder results of the combination of economics and law, such as Judge Posner's 1993 comment that "[a]t the heart of economic analysis of law is a mystery that is also an embarrassment: how to explain judicial behavior in economic terms. . . .”  In the spirit of Thomas Kuhn's The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, it seemed to me fair to trace this particular convergenceImages of philosophy, science, and economics.  (I've done it before, but more people will read this post in a couple hours than have combined read the essay!)

The image that comes to mind is that game in which you start with one word, and by changing it one letter at a time into a series of different words, you finally end up at a word that is the opposite of, or an ironic twist on, the original word.  Remember what Adam Smith's invisible hand was?  The wealth of nations comes about from individual Images-1 self-interest.  "It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest."  That is, each individual doesn't worry about creating a better world, but a better world comes about regardless.  (That's why Judge Posner correctly says that classical microeconomics doesn't try to get inside the head of each actor - it just assumes the actors, as a whole, are rational in seeking their self-interest, like rational frogs.)  But the combination of law and economics has produced (incrementally, I think, like the word game) a "scientific" orthodoxy or paradigm (see Kuhn) in which it's assumed that the butcher, brewer, baker, or frog actually has societal welfare maximization inside his or her head when making decisions.  (Steve Bainbridge expressed this in economic jargon the other day.  Corporate boards don't generally make decisions based on pareto-optimality, i.e., making everybody better off; they make "Kaldor-Hicks" decisions, which means that they are looking to maximize the corporation's share of any consumer surplus without regard to its overall impact on society.  That's what we all do every time we haggle with somebody over the price of the goods or services.)  This transformation (or Kuhnian paradigm) completes itself in models like the justification of contract formalism proffered by Alan Schwartz and Robert Scott (contracting parties really do want to maximize the joint surplus, not their individual share of it), or Ronald Gilson's justification of lawyering, in which he theorizes the only reason lawyers are present is because they have to increase the value of the total deal, not just each party's Kaldor-Hicks share.  I've criticized both of those models in other pieces.

Here's my Kuhnian thesis.  About a hundred years ago, the dominant philosophy of science was logical positivism.  (This was the Vienna Circle.)  The idea was that only the observable had any meaning at all - metaphysics was meaningless, including any attempt to posit a priori concepts like causation in the explanation of the world.  In other words, the only appropriate tools in the scientific tool box were observations of regularities, and the use of deductive logic.  The logical positivists viewed any attempt to explain one event in terms of another by way of "causation," for example, as without meaning.  From this basis, Carl Hempel developed his "covering laws" thesis, Popper rejected the verification principle in favor of falsification, and so on.  The point is that philosophers of science were rejecting Kantian metaphysics in favor of a strict empiricism.  What we want to do is identify the regularities, not try to explain why they are occurring.

I don't think it's a coincidence that the concepts of legal positivism were developing at about the same time.  Hans Kelsen developed his "Pure Theory of Law" to identify positive law, but it turned on neo-Kantian metaphysics expressed in the fundamental Grundnorm, an a priori concept (i.e., one accessible to us merely by reason, and preceding our experience of the world) by which physical events took on legal consequence.  H.L.A. Hart's positivism put aside the metaphysics, but substituted the Rule of Recognition, and the "internal point of view."  That's the key move:  the melding of the objective and observable (i.e., positive) with the subjective and internal.  Note the paradox that is now simply ignored.  We observe people stopping at red lights and going on green lights, but that only tells us there's a norm.  What makes it law, objectively and positively, is the subjective view of the individual from the internal point of view - the placement of the traffic light traces back to a "Rule of Recognition" by which the subjective actor recognizes the light has having the force of law.

So, economics is a science in the logical positivist tradition.  It ought not try to speculate why things are happening, but to explain or predict regularities.  If marginal costs exceed marginal revenues, generally the firm will shut down production.  If interest rates go down, generally demand for houses will go up.  The explanation of law, on the other hand, in the positivist tradition at least, demands that we look at the internal point of view; otherwise we may be studying norms and not law.  Note again that there is a metaphysical paradox that Hartian legal positivism just doesn't contemplate.  The incremental result of combining the two - the external point of view of economics and the internal point of view of law - is the mish-mash in which, against all intuitive good sense, the theory demands (see Schwartz and Scott or Gilson as evidence) individual actors incorporate the external point of view in their internal motivations!

To me, reading these accounts of motivation is as strange as if reading a theorist in quantum mechanics who felt obliged to explain the individual motivations of the electrons versus merely predicting where they'd be.

http://lawprofessors.typepad.com/legal_profession/2009/05/the-invisible-hand-meets-the-internal-point-of-view-the-strange-mishmash-of-law-economics.html

Economics, Law & Society | Permalink

TrackBack URL for this entry:

http://www.typepad.com/services/trackback/6a00d8341bfae553ef01156f81b2c9970c

Listed below are links to weblogs that reference The Invisible Hand Meets the Internal Point of View: The Strange Mish-Mash of Law & Economics:

Comments

Re: "individual actors incorporate the external point of view in their internal motivations!"

You may or may not know but that is exactly, or perhaps quite similar to, what Ian Hacking talks about with his notion of "looping effects" in the context of some forms of mental illness, i.e., that which occurs when people change their behaviour in response to the ways in which they are classified (those that are 'human kinds' rather than 'natural kinds' of disorders). In short, there is a "feedback' between the classification and the people being classified.

[Much, much more could be said about this, but I have to help evacuate my in-laws in Santa Barbara owing to the Jesusita fire. Last night we evacuated my son and his wife and then Mrs. Nandini Iyer. It's really ugly here in Santa Barbara... Pray for us!]

Posted by: Patrick S. O'Donnell | May 8, 2009 7:27:19 AM

Patrick,
Are you guys OK?
Alan

Posted by: Alan Childress | May 9, 2009 1:48:00 PM

Alan,

Yes, very much so (although our condo became akin to a small one room Moscow apartment during a heat wave, it was actually nice seeing everybody, even if under such awful conditions): I hope my bracketed comment wasn't too alarmist but about 30% of the city's residents (over 30,000) were under mandatory evacuation as the flames came close to the city (the fire stretched from Goleta to Montecito). Both of my brothers' families nearby were also among those evacuated. Unfortunately, our small condo couldn't take them all in and our in-laws cannot easily negotiate our stairs (all bedrooms upstairs), so we had to find them accommodations in the city (and they ended up getting themselves out--they're well into their 80s--as they were all packed up and ready to go when they heard about the order to leave). We knew quite a few others who had to leave as well.

Many folks were able to find family and friends within reasonable range but others went to emergency shelters at a local high school and UC Santa Barbara, and yet others, like my in-laws, found accommodations at hotels, motels, and bed-and-breakfast joints, and even the swankiest hotels offered discounts for evacuees, so everyone has come through, as often happens during such emergencies.

What was so unnerving were the extremely intense and unpredictable "sundowner" winds which push the flames down the hills toward the city (of course there's a fair number of people who live up in the hills) and indeed can push the flames in virtually any direction except back upon the fire itself. Typically in Southern California we have to worry about the Santa Ana winds, but these localized winds are, for us at least, often far more dangerous (sometimes the two are in combination). The city is covered by soot and ash: it's hard to describe how ugly it can get and the air is close to unbreathable (and is so among people with respiratory problems), especially in the early evening when it looks like some fantasied image of the apocalypse.

Apparently we lost more homes from the recent Tea Fire but it's been quite a one-two punch from these recent fires (the media often gives the impression that these fires are burning the mansions of the rich and famous, but many others have lost their homes as well and of course it doesn't matter how wealthy you are, to lose your home in this manner is quite devastating as there's usually absolutely nothing left to salvage). In any case, class, status and privilege go up in flames during these times, one of the beneficial by-products.

Weather has improved immensely today and they announced 30% containment, so the firefighters are going on the offensive (they admitted to being in a defensive mode when the weather dictated the terms of the battle). They hope to be able to return at least some people to their homes soon, but they are worried about our weather forecast which seems to imply the possibility that sundowner-like conditions could recur in the coming week.

This is our third major fire within a year's time and we've been told to expect fire season now to be year round. Diane and I are intimately acquainted with what it's like to fight such fires as we met each other while on a USFS sponsored fire crew in the late 1970s. We were on a hand crew, and those individuals have the hardest and perhaps the most dangerous tasks during the height of the fire. The fire is also named after a well-known trail that begins in a park close to the elementary school both our children attended. The Jesusita trail is one of the local "front country" (i.e., on this side of the mountains) trails we worked on in our youth.

Well, TMI (too much information), as our daughter frequently tells me in response to one of my animated narrations, but it was considerate of you to ask. And of course I know you have experience with another type of natural (and man-made) disaster....

Posted by: Patrick S. O'Donnell | May 9, 2009 4:12:18 PM

Post a comment