Friday, March 27, 2015

Eric Hellend at Northwestern Law---March 30

Eric Helland, William F. Podlich Professor of Economics and George R. Roberts Fellow, Claremont McKenna College
Estimating Effects of English Rule on Litigation Outcomes

March 27, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Marina Halac at Columbia Law School--March 30

Marina Halac, David W. Zalaznick Associate Professor of Business, Columbia Business School

"Contests for Experimentation"

Abstract: We study the design of contests for specific innovations when there is learning: contestants’ beliefs dynamically evolve about both the innovation’s feasibility and opponents’ success. Our model builds on exponential-bandit experimentation. We characterize contests that maximize the probability of innovation when the designer chooses how to allocate a prize and what information to disclose over time about contestants’ successes. A “public winner-takes-all contest” dominates public contests—those where any success is immediately disclosed—with any other prize-sharing scheme as well as winner-takes-all contests with any other disclosure policy. Yet, it is often optimal to use a “hidden equal-sharing contest”.

March 27, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Monday, March 23, 2015

Jill Fisch at NYU Law--March 24

Jill Fisch, University of Pennsylvania Law School
Paper Topic:  PROVOKING CORPORATE GOVERNANCE INNOVATION: THE CASE OF THE GOLDEN LEASH

March 23, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Emiliano Catan and Marcel Kahan at Harvard Law School--March 24

 Emiliano Catan (NYU) and Marcel Kahan* (NYU), The Law and Finance of Anti-Takeover Statutes

March 23, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Tuesday, March 17, 2015

Reaching the Moon by Climbing a Tree

"A man  tried to get to the moon by climbing a tree. It almost worked. He reported steady progress--- all the way to the top of the tree. "

 (I forget where I got this idea. It sounds like a Chinese  proverb; I think it would work well in characters. Google Translate gives " 一個人試圖去月球通過爬樹。它幾乎工作。他報導穩步推進---一路樹的頂端," which returns as "A person trying to use the trees to the moon. It's almost working.   He reported steadily all the way to the top of the tree." But something more succinct is needed--- it should only take half that number of characters.)

 

                 

月亮

March 17, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Monday, March 16, 2015

Do We Know What Happened to the JD Class of 2010?

Deborah Jones Merritt ("DJM"), a law professor at Ohio State, has posted a new paper analyzing employment outcomes for recent law graduates.  DJM does a fantastic amount of legwork, collecting the late-2014 employment status for more than 1,000 lawyers admitted to the Ohio bar around 2010.  From these data, she makes some claims (of increasingly problematic nature) about the path of employment progress for those lawyers, for lawyers around the country, and for legal education.  

This would be an excellent paper if DJM had been content to offer us a snapshot of employment outcomes for a cross-section of new lawyers in a second-tier legal market.  It's a sobering picture, with about one-sixth of the pool in "solo practice," which she convincingly shows often equates to a struggle to make ends meet.   And the methodology -- hand-gathering results for every lawyer -- is impressive.

My problem is that instead DJM wants to offer us a dynamic analysis, comparing 2014 to 2011, and arguing that the resulting differential tells us that there has been a "structural shift" in the market for lawyers.  It might be that the data exist somewhere to conduct that kind of analysis, but if so they aren't in the paper.  Nearly all the analysis in the paper is built on the tend line between DJM's 2014 Ohio results and national-average survey results from NALP.  

Let me say that again.  Almost everything DJM says is built on a mathematical comparison between two different pools whose data were constructed using different methods.  I would not blame you if now stopped reading.  But below the jump, some elaboration.

Continue reading

March 16, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (2)

Sunday, March 15, 2015

Napoleon on Incompetence

“Never ascribe to malice that which can adequately be explained by incompetence.”

                                                                                                                                        ― Napoleon

This is something we who use game theory need to keep in mind, both in modelling and in daily life. 

March 15, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Galle on time and the choice of regulatory instruments

Of course, comments & suggestions are very welcome.

***

Brian D. Galle, Boston College Law School 

March 13, 2015

Vanderbilt Law Review, Forthcoming 


Abstract:      

Timing is an important consideration in regulatory design. Corrective taxes are usually imposed before or contemporaneously with the harmful activity they are aimed at preventing, while tort awards are assessed ex post, in its aftermath. Patents and research grants both can encourage innovation, but patents pay off only after the invention is marketed. In a world of perfect information, fully rational actors, and complete credit or insurance markets, time would not matter. In the real world, though, the failure of one or more of these assumptions can change dramatically the impact of a regulatory option. For example, prior commentators have largely favored ex post incentives on the ground that government has much better information after the regulated activity is complete. 

This Article argues that the consensus in favor of ex post regulation overlooks some important considerations. Ex post regulation does provide useful additional information when regulated parties are heterogeneous, but also carries significant and sometimes prohibitive social cost, especially when externalities are produced by limited-liability firms. Further, drawing on results from mathematical simulations, I show that the costs of heterogeneity can be sharply reduced with even modest up-front information. I apply these insights to a series of examples, including the obesity crisis, the regulation of systemic risk in the banking sector, state fiscal failures, and the design of the IP system.

March 15, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Wednesday, March 11, 2015

Gelbach: Can Empirical Evidence Tell Us the Effects of Twombly & Iqbal?

Material Facts in the Debate Over Twombly and Iqbal" Free Download 
68 Stan. L. Rev. ___ (2016) (Forthcoming)

JONAH B. GELBACHUniversity of Pennsylvania Law School

This paper presents empirical evidence concerning the adjudication of defendant-filed summary judgment motions from nearly 2,000 randomly selected employment discrimination and contracts cases to try to assess Twombly and Iqbal’s performance in filtering cases according to merit. I first explain how such data might be helpful in such an assessment, taking into account the possibility that parties’ behavior might have changed following Twombly and Iqbal. 

I then report results indicating that even using this large collection of data -- the most comprehensive data assembled to date to address this question -- we cannot tell whether “TwIqbal” supporters or critics are more correct about the efficacy of the new plausibility pleading regime in the pre-discovery filtering of cases according to merit. This null result points to the very real possibility that plausibility pleading’s case-quality effects -- a quintessential empirical question -- simply can't be answered using data. 

This paper’s basic message, then, is that empirical evidence is unlikely to settle the debate over the case-quality effects of the new pleading regime ushered in by Twombly and Iqbal.

March 11, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Tuesday, March 10, 2015

Important New Methods Paper from Eisenbergs, Wells, & Zhang

"Addressing the Zeros Problem: Regression Models for Outcomes with a Large Proportion of Zeros, with an Application to Trial Outcomes" Fee Download 
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, Vol. 12, Issue 1, pp. 161-186, 2015

THEODORE EISENBERGCornell University - Law School
THOMAS EISENBERGCornell University - Department of Economics
MARTIN T. WELLSCornell University - School of Law
MIN ZHANGDepartment of Statistics

In law‐related and other social science contexts, researchers need to account for data with an excess number of zeros. In addition, dollar damages in legal cases also often are skewed. This article reviews various strategies for dealing with this data type. Tobit models are often applied to deal with the excess number of zeros, but these are more appropriate in cases of true censoring (e.g., when all negative values are recorded as zeros) and less appropriate when zeros are in fact often observed as the amount awarded. Heckman selection models are another methodology that is applied in this setting, yet they were developed for potential outcomes rather than actual ones. Two‐part models account for actual outcomes and avoid the collinearity problems that often attend selection models. A two‐part hierarchical model is developed here that accounts for both the skewed, zero‐inflated nature of damages data and the fact that punitive damage awards may be correlated within case type, jurisdiction, or time. Inference is conducted using a Markov chain Monte Carlo sampling scheme. Tobit models, selection models, and two‐part models are fit to two punitive damage awards data sets and the results are compared. We illustrate that the nonsignificance of coefficients in a selection model can be a consequence of collinearity, whereas that does not occur with two‐part models.

March 10, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Friday, March 6, 2015

The Obama Administration Declares Full Agreement with the Ferguson Grand Jury Decision Not To Indict!

      President Obama’s Justice Department  has just issued "Department of Justice Report Regarding the Criminal Investigation into the Shooting Death of Michael Brown by Ferguson, Missouri Police Officer Darren Wilson" (March 4, 2015). It’s surprising. It unequivocally exonerates Officer Wilson and says that he was acting in self defense. It doesn’t just say, “there isn’t sufficient proof” or “we cannot say beyond a reasonable doubt”.  It goes into specifics and says that the conventional story, pushed by the mainstream media, was completely false. The Justice Department  has not only failed to indict Wilson, they have decided it’s not even worth bringing the matter before a federal grand jury.

  Will there be mass protests? Will Washington, D.C. be burned down? Will there be calls for President Obama to resign? Do black lives matter?

    I thought the Ferguson grand jury documents definitely proved Officer Wilson innocent, that the Ferguson grand jury acted correctly in not indicting, and that it was even questionable whether the prosecutor should have brought the matter before a grand jury (but probably justified in light of public concern, for transparency).  But that doesn’t seem to be the perception of many people, even educated people, though I don’t know if any of those people actually looked at the evidence. This could be the subject of a fascinating case study, perhaps even a comparative one comparing it to France’s Dreyfus case (though that took years to finish), on how elite opinion is formed by initial news reports and is hard to change even as more credible evidence appears.

 Some quotes from the Justice Department report:

Continue reading

March 6, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Monday, March 2, 2015

Expressive powers of Law (2015) by by Richard McAdams

 

I would like to highlight a great book, recently published, by Richard H. McAdams from Chicago Law School on the Expressive powers of Law. (Harvard University press 2015)

              The book brings together lots of research, which has been carried out throughout the years by McAdams and his co-authors on this important topic. McAdams, one of the most important scholars in this tradition, was among the first legal scholars to recognize that law can affect behavior not only through sanctions and morality.

I personally feel especially connected to the expressive function of the law since I have written my mostly experimental dissertation on this topic. What’s unique about the subject is that it captures something which many people feel lies somewhere between deterrence and moral/fairness based approaches to compliance but it is actually based on both. This approach is also unique in a sense that it represents research conducted by people from different disciplines, each suggesting a different account for what expressive law really captures.  For example, one of my PhD advisors, Bob Cooter, has developed a competing thesis to this topic. This concept has attracted scholars in the field of law and philosophy to write about it and people who focus on law and institutions have worked on it as well.

The specific thesis provided by McAdams focuses on the notion of information provided by the law as a way to help people coordinate their action. Clearly, the focus on information signaling and focal points brings to the table, something which is distinctively different than deterrence or internalization. Interestingly, while McAdams himself is mostly a Law and Economics scholar, he does review many of the relevant literatures from various other disciplines and analyses them.

However, at the same time it is clear that law serves as a much better focal point when it is seen as something that might be obeyed due to either extrinsic or intrinsic rationales. This is why it is important to recognize that this third "in between" type of effect of the law captures parts of the more traditional approach to the effect of law on behavior.

McAdams' book is also very interesting in a world where states now communicate with citizens through nudging them by various situational cues, which are sometimes beyond their awareness. Revisiting some of the more traditional effects of the law, when people are aware of the effects of it and can deliberate on its meaning, is therefore a highly needed task.

 

 

March 2, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Thursday, February 26, 2015

The FBI's Ten Most Wanted

Steve Sailer has a post,  Texas's Top 10 Most Wanted Fugitives Include 8 White Males .        (though all 8 are hispanic, as well as the one woman on the list). That made me curious about the FBI list. Here it is: 

TTemp

     The federal prison population is 34% hispanic, so that ratio matches the Ten Most Wanted pretty well. It's 7% female, which is also pretty close, but 38% black. I wonder whether the most serious criminals are really 40% WASP (we Norwegian-German-Americans feel a bit left out), or whether the choice is political. It might be interesting to look at the ethnic make-up over time. The FBI has a list of everybody who's ever been Most Wanted at http://www.fbi.gov/wanted/topten/ten-most-wanted-fugitives-faq/.

 

 

February 26, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Monday, February 23, 2015

Comments on Goolsbee and Krueger, “A Retrospective Look at Rescuing and Restructuring General Motors and Chrysler,”

Austan D. Goolsbee and Alan B. Krueger have just  posted a working paper, “A Retrospective Look at Rescuing and Restructuring General Motors and Chrysler,” that is going to be a Journal of Economic Perspectives article (I saw it via Marginal Revolution).  They were involved in the process in the Obama Administration. They think the rescue was a success, but I think there are some things about the process that they don’t notice, much less deal with. I’ll let them know about them, and maybe they’ll address them in the final version.

    The biggest problem to sort out is the difference between the accounting/legal and the economic assets.   When a company goes bankrupt, the first-order economic effect is zero, despite the drastic accounting/legal effect. The assets are the same as they were--- they’re just owned by different people. It’s not necessarily any different than when existing shareholders sell 60% of the stock to new shareholders. In bankruptcy, the existing shareholders are in effect forced to give up 100% of the stock to the people who lent them money they can’t repay. Often those people will decide the company isn’t worth keeping together, so they sell it off in pieces, at the extreme auctioning off the land, trucks, and furniture. But it’s not like a nuclear bomb hit the company’s property.

Continue reading

February 23, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Shouldn't They Have Titled It "All About the Benjamins"?

"U.S. Consumers’ Holdings and Use of $100 Bills" Free Download 
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Research Paper Series Research Data Reports No. 14-3

CLAIRE GREENEFederal Reserve Banks - Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
SCOTT D. SCHUHFederal Reserve Bank of Boston - Research Department

Conventional wisdom asserts that $100 bills are often associated with crime and foreign cash holdings, leading some commentators to call for their elimination; in light of this view, it is useful to examine the legal, domestic use of cash. This report uses new data from the 2012 Diary of Consumer Payment Choice (DCPC) to evaluate consumer use of $100 bills as a means of payment. On a typical day in the United States, 5.2 percent of consumers have a $100 bill in their pocket, purse, or wallet. But only 22 percent of U.S. consumers have at least $100 in their wallet, pocket, or purse. Of these cash-intensive consumers, the main association with holding a $100 bill is the amount of cash carried. A consumer who carries $400 to $699 has a 64 percent probability of carrying at least one $100 bill.

February 23, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (1)

Michal Gal and Daniel Rubinfield at Harvard Law on February 24, 2015

Michal Gal (Haifa) and Daniel Rubinfeld (Berkeley, NYU), The Hidden Costs of Free Goods: Implications for Antitrust Enforcement

February 23, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Sunday, February 22, 2015

Sure, crowdfunding under Title III doesn't work, but can we fix it?

Critics seems to agree that equity crowdfunding—the new exemption to the Securities Act that lets ordinary people invest in startup companies—is going to be a major flop.  Papers call it a “siren call,” a “promise unfulfilled,” “a market for lemons” and even “fraudfunding.”  The problems are many, but proposed solutions are few.  Instead of finding new holes to poke in the existing regulation (Title III of the JOBS Act of 2012), can we find a regulatory patch that makes crowdfunding work?

Yes we can find a valuable role for crowdfunding, but that means asking some new questions.  What is crowdfunding supposed to do, anyway?  First off, let’s be clear on what it won’t do: crowdfunding won’t fund small businesses.  Despite what Barack Obama said when signing the JOBS Act into law (“start-ups and small business will now have access to a big, new pool of potential investors”), small business remain terrible equity investments. They just don’t product rewards sufficient to offset their risks.  But crowdfunding can “democratize access to capital,” as the MIT Sloan innovation@work blog put it.  Can crowdfunding create the possibility of viable startups with new business models (not just iPhone apps) created by new entrepreneurs (not just white male founders) in new geographies (not just Silicon Valley)?

Crowdfunding as it's currently regulated won't democratize investment, but it could be restructured to fulfill this promise, and here’s how.  One: raise the crowdfunding limit from $1 million to $5 million. As Number Two said to Dr. Evil in the 1997 movie Austin Powers, “One million dollars isn’t exactly a lot of money these days.”  Startups—especially in relatively cost-intensive fields like hardware design and life sciences—need millions of dollars to get started.  For example, the Pebble smartwatch (the most successful crowdfunded campaign to date) needed $10 million to bring their product—which is now sold in BestBuy, WalMart, Amazon and Target—to market.

Two: require angels to invest before crowdfunding.  Crowds of folks investing $25 each don’t have proper incentives to protect themselves.  It’s rational for such small investors to be apathetic.  Crowdfunding is fraught with fraud risk because no one may be overseeing the investment.  Angels, who invest at least $10,000 (and often more) each—and do this for a living—are in a much better position to diligence, oversee and influence a brand new startup company.

My new paper talks about these and related topics in some depth, but the point is simple: the best way to protect crowdfunding investors is to let them invest enough money (collectively) in startups to protect themselves.  While the SEC is still pondering the exemption’s rulemaking, it’s high time to raise the limit so crowdfunding can actually democratize investment.  Voting with dollars only works when the money can be well spent.

For more in depth information and analysis, check on my new article on SSRN, Bridgefunding is Crowdfunding for Startups across the Private Equity Gap, at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2544365

By Seth C. Oranburg, Visiting Assistant Professor, Florida State University College of Law

February 22, 2015 in Current Affairs, Web/Tech | Permalink | Comments (0)

Tess Wilkinson-Ryan at Columbia Law School on February 23, 2015

Tess Wilkinson-Ryan, Assistant Professor of Law and Psychology, University of Pennsylvania Law School

"The Common Sense of Contract Formation"

"We find that indeed information that a contract has been legally formed has behavioral effects, enhancing parties’ commitments to a deal even when there are no associated formal sanctions. However, we also document a series of situations in which misunderstandings have limited practical repercussions, because even parties who believe that legal obligation is about formalities take seriously the moral obligations associated with informal expectations, promises and exchanges. "

February 22, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Friday, February 20, 2015

Age Discrimination in Academia and Silicon Valley

Tyler Cowen at Marginal Revolution has a post on age discrimination in academia. "I believe it is very bad, although I do not have data.  I believe that if a 46-year-old, with an excellent vita and newly minted Ph.D in hand, applied for academic economics jobs at the top fifty research universities, the individual would receive very few “bites.” - 

 I'm skeptical. There are plenty of lateral hires of 46-year-olds, with tenure. So why would a department be reluctant to hire a 46-year-old without tenure, who can be fired in 6 years without much problem? And who would have fewer years of life to be deadwood if he burned out? 

   To be sure, it would be odd for anyone to get a Ph.D at age 46, and difficult, given that we of mature years aren't as good at staying up all night doing problem sets or slaving away on the computer to get our professor's numbers ready for his talk the the next day.  And one has to wonder why the person wants to give up 5 or 6 of the most productive years of his life to acquire expertise in a new field in the company of 22-year-olds and start on a career track that is highly risky even for the most talented. But if someone did, and could show a good reason for doing so  (like having made his pile on Wall Street and deciding that he loved economic theory), would he really not get job offers?  I only know of one case. That was a woman whose husband was a big-name professor and whose kids had grown up. She got a PhD in accounting (a  rigorous PhD, with plenty of economics and finance), and got a good job immediately, in the same university as her husband.

    The comments were quite interesting. Most of them were about age discrimination in high-tech. There was strong disagreement as to whether (a) Silicon Valley discriminates in favor of women and minorities or against them, and (b) whether there is massive discrimination against men over 45, or no discrimination against them. A friend here in Boston said that he knows lots of middle-aged dads without jobs because they got too old for their well-paid high-tech jobs.  Why the industry doesn’t want them is a good question. I am told that in prestigious law firms the situation is not as dissimilar as you might think, because many older partners are pressured to retire early by the few who run the firms. 

February 20, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)

Thursday, February 19, 2015

Top Downloads in L&E Public Law, 2/20/15

RECENT TOP PAPERS for all papers first announced in the last 60 days  
21 Dec 2014 through 19 Feb 2015

RankDownloadsPaper Title
1 260 Friedrich Hayek's Contribution to Antitrust Law and Its Modern Application 
Thibault Schrepel 
University of Versailles 
Date posted to database: 12 Jan 2015 
Last Revised: 29 Jan 2015
2 135 The Effect of Regulatory Harmonization on Cross-Border Labor Migration: Evidence from the Accounting Profession 
Matthew J. BloomfieldUlf BrüggemannHans Bonde Christensen and Christian Leuz 
University of Chicago - Booth School of Business, Humboldt University of Berlin - School of Business and Economics, University of Chicago - Booth School of Business and University of Chicago - Booth School of Business 
Date posted to database: 19 Jan 2015 
Last Revised: 24 Jan 2015
3 89 Explaining Race Gaps in Policing: Normative and Empirical Challenges 
Sonja B. Starr 
University of Michigan Law School 
Date posted to database: 15 Jan 2015 
Last Revised: 21 Jan 2015
4 81 The Law and Economics of Proportionality in Discovery 
Jonah B. Gelbach and Bruce H. Kobayashi 
University of Pennsylvania Law School and George Mason University - School of Law 
Date posted to database: 20 Jan 2015 
Last Revised: 28 Jan 2015
5 70 Behavioral Public Choice: The Behavioral Paradox of Government Policy 
W. Kip Viscusi and Ted Gayer 
Vanderbilt University - Law School and Brookings Institution 
Date posted to database: 4 Feb 2015 
Last Revised: 4 Feb 2015
6 69 The Politics and Economics of Metropolitan Sprawl 
William A. Fischel 
Dartmouth College - Department of Economics 
Date posted to database: 23 Jan 2015 
Last Revised: 24 Jan 2015
7 68 Wynne v. Comptroller: It's Not About Double Taxation 
Michael S. Knoll and Ruth Mason 
University of Pennsylvania Law School and University of Virginia School of Law 
Date posted to database: 16 Jan 2015 
Last Revised: 6 Feb 2015
8 61 The Broader Implications of Merger Remedies in High Technology Markets 
D. Daniel Sokol 
University of Florida - Levin College of Law 
Date posted to database: 18 Dec 2014 
Last Revised: 18 Dec 2014
9 59 On the Inefficiencies of Efficiency as the Single-Minded Goal of Antitrust 
Albert Foer 
American Antitrust Institute (AAI) 
Date posted to database: 11 Jan 2015 
Last Revised: 11 Jan 2015
10 57 Does Access Encourage Science? Evidence from the WWII Book Replication Program 
Barbara Biasi and Petra Moser 
Stanford University - Department of Economics and Stanford University - Department of Economics 
Date posted to database: 26 Dec 2014 
Last Revised: 28 Jan 2015

February 19, 2015 | Permalink | Comments (0)